[I'm not fully happy with this post. I think it does an OK job of explaining SRAS shocks that the central bank accommodates. But it doesn't say what happens when the central bank does not accommodate SRAS shocks. And I would like to integrate George Selgin's analysis of SRAS shocks in Less Than Zero, which I haven't yet done. But I'm posting it anyway.]
When we teach Intro Macro we usually draw a diagram something like this:
Sometimes we draw the SRAS (Short Run Aggregate Supply) curve as horizontal, but that doesn't matter for this post. Sometimes we put the inflation rate rather than the price level on the vertical axis, and call the SRAS curve the Short Run Phillips Curve, but that doesn't matter for this post. And the SRAS curve is not, strictly, a supply curve, but that doesn't matter for this post.
The SRAS curve incorporates the fact that the average price level seems to be sticky, so that (sudden, unexpected) shifts in the AD (Aggregate Demand) curve cause real output Y to change. The LRAS (Long Run Aggregate Supply) curve allows the average price level to adjust (though relative prices may still be sticky). A (sudden) leftward shift in the AD curve would cause a recession, like the one shown in the diagram. Optimal policy tries to prevent any (sudden) shifts in the AD curve, so the economy is always where the SRAS and LRAS curves intersect, at potential output Y*.
But the SRAS and LRAS curves may also shift.
If the SRAS and LRAS curves always shift left (or right) by exactly the same amount, then optimal AD policy is to ensure that the price level (or inflation rate) is unaffected by those "supply shocks". You can think of this as shifting the AD curve left by that exact same amount, or think of it as making the AD curve horizontal. Targeting inflation, or the price level, is optimal. There's a "divine coincidence" between preventing fluctuations in the price level (or inflation) and preventing output gaps between actual Y and potential Y*.
But sometimes the SRAS curve seems to shift left (or right) by more than the LRAS curve. Or, if the SRAS curve is horizontal, you can think of the SRAS curve as sometimes shifting vertically up (or down). So the AD curve needs to allow the price level to rise (or the inflation rate to rise temporarily) if you wanted to keep the economy where SRAS and LRAS curves intersect, so Y=Y*. Shifting the AD curve left by a large enough amount to keep the price level unchanged (or making the AD curve horizontal) is bad policy. Divine coincidence fails. Strict inflation targeting is bad policy. We call these "SRAS shocks", or "price level shocks".
And those SRAS shocks are what is very hard to teach. (It's very easy to teach "If it's a short shock to supply it shifts SRAS, and if it's a long shock to supply it shifts LRAS", but that's wrong.) And what makes it especially hard to teach is that us teachers don't really understand them either.
Here is a story of SRAS shocks:
Recent Comments