When an Ontario cemetery operator sells a burial plot, they must side aside 40 percent of the money they receive into a "care and maintenance account". This is a way of solving a grave moral hazard problem: operators might sell plots, and then walk away from their maintenance obligations.
The same kind of moral hazard problem exists in resource extraction industries, and is solved in a not-entirely-dissimilar way. Operators are typically required to post bonds, or contribute to an "orphan well fund" or a "mine financial security program." If an company walks away from a toxic waste site once operations have ended, the funds from the security program can be used to pay for site clean-up.
The only problem is that the amounts in these clean-up funds are typically tiny relative to the potential costs of site clean-up. This point has been raised by the Pembina Institute, in their report on How Albertans Could End Up Playing for Oil Site Mine Reclamation. It's been raised in an expert panel report on Environmental and Health Impacts of the Oil Sands Industry, commissioned by the Royal Society of Canada. It has been noted by the Auditor General of Alberta and the BC Auditor General.
The risks associated with future toxic waste from the oil sands are, in some ways, more worrying than the much more widely known global warming ones. Humans could possibly adapt to a warmer climate. But the arsenic-laced water around the NWT's Giant Mine? That's unequivocally, inevitably lethal. The issue is more pressing than ever this year, given the federal government's decision to approve the Trans Mountain Pipeline, and their announcement that they will be welcoming more foreign investment (if it's hard to stop a Canadian operator from walking away from a toxic waste site, how will it be possible to stop a foreign one?).
Why hasn't more attention been paid to the environmental risks of resource extraction? My theory is that the human brain is just not very good at processing low-probability, ultra-high-cost events. We can't differentiate, at an emotional level, between someone defecating on our driveway, and someone contaminating the entire Athabaska watershed. We just can't grasp - or don't want to grasp - the enormity of the environmental disaster the oil sands could create.
My contribution to this year's Macleans "chart of the year" competition attempted to convey the environmental risks of the oil sands in a way that made them intelligible to the typical educated and informed Canadian. The chart and the post follows below. The graphics aren't great. Here are the raw numbers: Download Oil sands v tar ponds. I would welcome suggestions for alternative and better ways of presenting this data.
The following was originally published in Macleans.
"Resource extraction is profitable. Cleaning up the mess it makes is not. In the past, owners have often walked away from their operations, leaving others to pay the clean-up bill.
The Sydney Tar Ponds show how expensive that clean-up can be. Although the Sydney site totalled just over 100 hectares, the 2004-14 clean-up operations cost federal and Nova Scotia taxpayers $400 million – about $4 million per hectare.
Alberta’s oil sands are hundreds of times bigger than the Sydney Tar Ponds. To pre-commit companies to paying for the eventual costs of reclaiming oil sands sites, the Alberta government has created a “Mine Financial Security Program”. Companies wishing to mine the oil sands must post a base amount of security for each project. In theory, they could be required to post additional securities. In practice that never happens.
Right now there is $939 million deposited into the Mine Financial Security Program. That’s about $43,000 for each hectare of tailing ponds in the oil sands. The total deposits in the Mine Financial Security program would fund two Sydney Tar Pond size clean-ups. Unsurprisingly, the Auditor General of Alberta is concerned this amount is inadequate.
Suncor is the largest operator in the oil sands. In the first three quarters of 2016, it produced 1.4 million barrels from its oil sands operations. Its total cash flow was $3.6 billion. Its net new contributions to the Mine Financial Security Program? Zero."
Update:
Here are some other ways of representing the data. The first two are from Declan:
And here's one from Isaac Holloway via twitter:
I actually like Declan's second idea; the challenge is showing the areas accurately.
Sources: size of Sydney Tar Ponds: http://www.ceaa.gc.ca/052/details-eng.cfm?pid=8989; size of Oil Sands Tailing Ponds: http://www.energy.alberta.ca/Oilsands/791.asp; cost of tar ponds clean-up: http://www.tpsgc-pwgsc.gc.ca/bve-oae/rapports-reports/2014-2015/2013-602-eng.html#a3.1; size of MFSP: https://www.aer.ca/documents/liability/AnnualMFSPSubmissions.pdf; Alberta auditor general report: https://www.oag.ab.ca/webfiles/reports/OAG%20Report%20July%202015.pdf; Suncor financial statements: http://www.suncor.com/investor-centre/financial-reports/quarterly-reports
Making matters more complicated, 'posting a bond' might not be enough legally speaking. The Supreme Court of Canada has ruled that some environmental-cleanup regulations are, in bankruptcy, treated like any other creditor.
On the other hand, this is ultimately an insurance problem and it could be regulated along those lines. Cleanup is a large, uncertain, and long-term liability, so it would make sense for operators to post not a fixed-size bond for cleanup but instead to submit proof of a current insurance contract that covers clean-up liability. The insurance contract and insurer would out-live any single mining operator.
This would also promote a virtuous cycle in resource extraction itself. At the moment, mine operators have every incentive to disregard future cleanup costs in favour of current profits, since the latter can be remitted to investors and the former can be left for bankruptcy. If the mine operators needed to maintain cleanup insurance, however, then the insurer would have financial incentives to ensure best environmental practices, and it would have the leverage (via the premium) to push those costs onto the mine operator.
Posted by: Majromax | December 13, 2016 at 11:58 AM
"This is a way of solving a GRAVE moral hazard problem"
Frances,
I presume this was not an intended pun? :-)
Posted by: Henry | December 13, 2016 at 12:04 PM
Is reclamation an eventuality for all sites, or only for those that suffer a spill/accident? I ask because if all sites will eventually incur the costs of repayment, development should be taxed like any externality. Something in the neighbourhood the $3,880,000/hectare realized in Sydney.
But if this is a low probability event, isn't the Mine Financial Security Programme an insurance programme? In that case, the fair premium per hectare is loss*probability of loss. If the probability of an accident is low (say 1%), they might be paying a fair premium at $43,000/hectare
Treating it like any old actuarially fair insurance sounds right to me in theory, but something about it feels wrong.
Posted by: Nikola | December 13, 2016 at 03:14 PM
Nikola: "Is reclamation an eventuality for all sites"
I'm not sure how to answer your question. Are you asking: does reclamation always happen? The answer to that question is definitely no. Often sites are simply abandoned, and no remediation is done unless there is an immediate danger to human health. But unfortunately the dangers associated with mining operations might not be realized until years after the mine has closed - see, for example, this article describing homes in danger of collapsing because they were built over mines that closed over 100 years ago.
"Treating it like any old actuarially fair insurance sounds right to me in theory" - but in practice no one knows either the probability of an accident, such as a tailing pond dam collapse, occurring, nor the size of the loss that would be incurred if, say, the waste from one of the tailing ponds leaked into the Athabasca River. This is a situation of Knightian uncertainty, not risk. No one wants to sell this insurance.
Posted by: Frances Woolley | December 13, 2016 at 03:27 PM
Henry: "I presume...." Er... that would be a strong presumption.
Posted by: Frances Woolley | December 13, 2016 at 03:28 PM
Majromax: Your point about bankruptcy laws is a really interesting one - I didn't know that.
"This would also promote a virtuous cycle in resource extraction itself."
Interesting idea. In some ways the various mine financial security programs are intended to act like an insurance program, but governments are too gutless to charge anything like an actuarially fair insurance premium - indeed, it's not obvious that mining would be financially viable if operators had to buy actuarially fair clean-up costs insurance.
Posted by: Frances Woolley | December 13, 2016 at 03:33 PM
Isn't Actuarially Fair insurance outcome-dependant under Knightian uncertainty? This would mean not only a higher premium, but ex post payments from mining companies depending on the size of the realized loss.
That might be more politically palatable than a premium that makes mining companies insolvent prior to loss.
Posted by: Nikola | December 13, 2016 at 04:31 PM
Having been involved in the mining/exploration business for a good part of my professional life, I am acutely aware of the issues in involved.
There is not only heavy metal pollutants to be concerned about as Frances mentioned, there is also acid producing species in mine wastes which inevitably leak out into water systems if not adequately controlled.
There is also the physical stability of waste containment systems. For instance, the collapse of the Samarco Mine tailings storage facility had deadly consequences.
There is also the general despoiling of land and ruination of its environmental amenity.
Environmental destruction can also take place with the consent of local authorities. The wholesale disposal of tailings from the OK Tedi mine in PNG into a river system also had a devastating impact.
Not all mining companies are cavalier in their attitude to environmental matters. However, they are probably in the minority.
Frances said: "it's not obvious that mining would be financially viable if operators had to buy actuarially fair clean-up costs insurance."
If ALL mining jurisdictions applied the same strict rules and conditions, there would be no escape for any mining companies. The cost of environmental liabilities would/could then be passed on (without competitive disadvantage) to the consumers of mineral products. That must occur otherwise the viability of the mining industry could/would be in question and there might/would be no investment in mining projects. If the world's consumers want mineral products, they have to bear the costs, all of them, ultimately.
Posted by: Henry | December 13, 2016 at 05:48 PM
Nikola: "but ex post payments from mining companies depending on the size of the realized loss."
The problem is that by the time it comes for the ex post payments to be made, the operators have long since disappeared, so the taxpayer ends up paying the bill.
If it's not profitable to extract resources and at the same time set aside an amount that covers future clean-up costs, perhaps those resources shouldn't be extracted in the first place.
Posted by: Frances Woolley | December 13, 2016 at 06:12 PM
The mine cleanup is certainly a potential problem.
In my mind, there is a parallel with unfunded pensions for employees, especially government employees. In both cases, the eventual liability falls on future wage earners.
The best solution that I can see is to build, as we mine, a very long lasting, stable environment. For pensions, the same by expecting each retiree to provide the vast majority of his own retirement.
Posted by: Roger Sparks | December 13, 2016 at 07:16 PM
Purely on the presentation, I think 3-D bar charts are pretty universally disliked for distorting size comparisons even if they look fancier than 2-D ones.
Also if the cleanup funds are per hectare, why bother graphing the size? (Graph the size and the total cleanup fund?)
Maybe better to have bars for the two different sites grouped together, and separate the size/fund comparisons, rather than vice-versa.
And to be really picky, having "$43" on the label and then having to figure out it is actually $43,000/hectare is a bit annoying.
Sorry these are more negative than constructive suggestions. Maybe an "infographic" style picture would be better than a straight graph. This might not fit the Macleans format, although "The income tax system and low-income households" is not a chart at all.
In general I found the Macleans charts pretty horrible for readability (compared to the Economist, say). Much too complicated and messy.
Posted by: Declan | December 13, 2016 at 09:20 PM
@Roger Sparks:
Regarding pensions, Canada is cleaning up its act there. At the federal level, government-worker pensions were split into a legacy unfunded component prior to 2000 and an advance-funded component accruing thereafter.
For very long-lived entities such as governments, advance-funded defined-benefit pensions make sense as a beneficial transfer of risk. Workers have variable and shortening horizons making them collectively risk-adverse, whereas governments can invest in a risk-neutral manner
Posted by: Majromax | December 14, 2016 at 10:10 AM
@Declan is right about the presentation. If you are going to do charts you should invest some time in reading Edward Tufte's books.
You should also figure out how to make them required reading for your students.
Macleans graphics people should be hit with a big cluebat and these books.
Posted by: Jim Rootham | December 14, 2016 at 10:38 AM
On the substance, given the current power relations do you see any hope for a solution to this problem?
Posted by: Jim Rootham | December 14, 2016 at 10:42 AM
Jim -
It's easy to write "you should". The problem is not figuring out what a nice graph *should* look like, the problem is figuring out how to make some program create that graph.
What I'd really appreciate is if you could download the data - there's a link to the spreadsheet in the post above - and explain how to use excel to make a prettier diagram.
If what "you should" really means is "you should spend a a month learning such-and-such language" or "you should spend hundreds of dollars on such-and-such software" then, sorry, not going to happen.
Posted by: Frances Woolley | December 14, 2016 at 11:17 AM
Jim - on the substantive point you raise...
No.
Posted by: Frances Woolley | December 14, 2016 at 11:17 AM
Jim - on the required readings for students issue - I am teaching a professional practice course next term, so am grateful for any and all suggestions. Edward Tufte's stuff looks great - my concern is that it would be a bit over the head of my students, who need to be taught basic good practice e.g. labelling axes.
Posted by: Frances Woolley | December 14, 2016 at 12:08 PM
Frances said: "If it's not profitable to extract resources and at the same time set aside an amount that covers future clean-up costs, perhaps those resources shouldn't be extracted in the first place."
I said: "If the world's consumers want mineral products, they have to bear the costs, all of them, ultimately."
I might walk back a little from my comment. Mining, like any other enterprise produces social benefit/costs, environmental costs (probably no environmental benefits) as well as private benefits/costs. The equation can be extremely complex from a range of view points which I won't go into. So who should bear the costs?
The social costs (demise of a way of life) of the Panguna copper/gold mine, for instance, became too much to bear for the local communities on Bougainville. They took up arms and forcibly closed the mine down, fighting a war with the national PNG government over the issue. The local people prevailed - the mine has remained closed for 30 years or so, yet it is one of the biggest copper/gold resources on the planet.
I am not saying that Albertans should take up arms or alternatively sit back and do nothing, but at least should look at the complete equation and weigh up the considerations. In Australia, there has been a huge fight over coal seam gas and shale oil/gas. Apart from the environmental considerations there is the competing commercial interests of farmers and miners. Another complication on the equation. The farmers are winning in many jurisdictions.
The mining industry is by and large a dirty business and should be held to book, but the equation is not that simple.
Posted by: Henry | December 14, 2016 at 02:03 PM
Frances,
I made something in Excel that I think looks better, I tried sending it to your Carleton email but in case it gets spam filtered or something:
1. Switch from 3-D to 2-D
2. Switch rows and columns in 'Select Data' (so the size and cash comparisons have the 2 sites side by side).
3. Use a log scale so the Sydney site size doesn't disappear
4. Do absolute size in hectares as well as/instead of the $/hectare
5. Write the labels manually in text boxes so you can pick your own units without messing up the scale and readers don't need to look at the legend to figure them out - not too much work with 4 or 6 data points (I was too lazy to actually do this though)
I don't know if this is 'prettier' but I think it gets the point across better - the oil sands are about 200 times bigger but only about twice as much in the cleanup fund.
Posted by: Declan | December 15, 2016 at 02:28 AM
But actually, the problem runs to all limited liability corporations, which is effectively a magic power bestowed by government that people operating under the legal framework of a corporation can do things that flesh and blood individuals would not legally be able to do. There are regular arguments amongst libertarians on this topic.
Well it has to be that way, otherwise we would need some reason why this particular operation was unique.Posted by: Tel | December 18, 2016 at 04:35 AM
Seems to me that the only effect of this is to ensure plots are more expensive than otherwise, and that the money in the "care and maintenance account" does get spent at some stage (possibly some of it might even go towards care and maintenance). There's no way for the dead guy to complain about the quality of the upkeep, and the remaining living relatives have already handed the money over.
Posted by: Tel | December 18, 2016 at 04:39 AM
Tel: "But actually, the problem runs to all limited liability corporations,"
Which is as good a reason as any for having a corporate tax - and one that I very rarely hear discussed.
I totally agree with second point about the further moral hazard problems created by the existence of an anti-moral-hazard care-and-maintenance account.
I've been asked to write a more extended piece on this issue, and that's one thing I'll have to deal with.
Posted by: Frances Woolley | December 18, 2016 at 11:25 AM
Frances: Apologies for doing a hit and run. I didn't track this for a while.
Without seeing it, it looks like Declan has dealt with the major issues with that chart.
Tufte is an amazingly clear and entertaining writer, if he is over anyones head, they are as thick as two short planks. OTOH a short and basic intro might well fit into the time constraints of a course better, but then they would miss the pleasures of reading and looking at Tufte's work.
Posted by: Jim Rootham | December 21, 2016 at 01:25 AM
Jim - I've posted Declan's charts above. Tufte has a whole bunch of books - which is the one you'd recommend to start with?
Thanks!
Posted by: Frances Woolley | December 21, 2016 at 01:05 PM
I would go with the first chart. People are better at comparing lengths than areas. Simplicity is a virtue.
I own "The Visual Display of Quantitative Information", so it's the one I am most familiar with. I believe it's his first book length publication. Without doing a detailed comparison I think that would be the best introductory work.
OTOH he has spent a lot of time teaching courses since then so a later work might be better
Posted by: Jim Rootham | December 21, 2016 at 07:52 PM
Upon consideration, given the small number of numbers you wish to display, I think a chart is a bad idea. Use a table. I think the following table tells the story (I think it is accurate, but I am not absolutely sure of the Sydney contributions by the company).
With respect to Tufte, he includes "The Visual Display of Quantitative Information" in his teaching package, so I am pretty sure the it is the best introduction/overview. Spending an afternoon(evening?:)) skimming the 4 books might be worthwhile.
Posted by: Jim Rootham | December 22, 2016 at 03:07 PM
The link below is to a talk by David Suzuki. Part way thru the talk (start at 35:10) he relates about an encounter with the CEO of one of the tar sands companies. It might be of interest to people here. It shows what you're up against. (The rest of the talk is pretty good too.)
http://mpegmedia.abc.net.au/rn/podcast/2016/12/ssw_20161224_1205.mp3
Posted by: Henry | December 25, 2016 at 07:09 PM