John Maynard Keynes famously wrote that: "Practical men, who believe themselves to be quite exempt from any intellectual influence, are usually the slaves of some defunct economist." A modern example of that dictum, relevant to the economy, policy, and markets, is the widespread view that people can "spend" their money, as if money represented a pool that is just waiting to "flow into" spending. Because such a thing cannot occur and therefore has not occurred, the point is usually made in reverse: people currently are not "spending" their money--rather they are "parking" their money at the bank or leaving it "idle." But that they might spend it in the future is a lurking risk and a reason to be cautious about the central bank engaging in aggressive quantitative easing (QE).
To see what is wrong with that standard textbook view, we need to consider the following fundamental accounting identity:
M = M
The amount of money that people hold must equal the amount of money created by the banking system. You can't see "spending" anywhere in that fundamental accounting identity, can you? Therefore, people do not "spend" money!
A key distinction to bear in mind is between individual people and people in aggregate. Neither individual people nor people as a whole can "spend" money, but individual people can and do offload their money (particularly excess money) by lending it to other people or by buying goods and assets; but people in aggregate cannot do this--in such cases, the money that leaves one person's balance sheet just pops up on another person's balance sheet, remaining on the banking system's balance sheet all the while.
Therefore, people cannot and do not "spend" money. This explains why creating money does not work to increase spending. Except, maybe, via obscure indirect mechanisms.
The above is total rubbish, of course. It is also heavily plagiarised, from an article by Paul Sheard (pdf) (HT David Andolfatto). Basically, I just changed his "banks" to "people", his "lend" to "spend", and his "reserves" to "money".
Now let me be sensible:
We define "excess money" as the actual stock of money that people hold minus the stock of money they desire to hold (given prices, income, interest rates etc.).
If an individual person has excess money, he can and will get rid of it, by spending it or by lending it. (And "lending" means "buying an IOU from someone", so it's the same as spending.) But that just means another individual person now holds it.
If the banking system creates an excess supply of money, and holds that stock of money constant, each individual person can get rid of it, but people in aggregate cannot get rid of it. It just keeps circulating back to them, as quickly as they spend it. But their individual attempts to get rid of it are what create the increased demand for goods, which will ultimately raise the prices of goods above what they would otherwise have been. The fact that people cannot in aggregate get rid of the excess money is a central part of the standard story of why excess money raises the demand for goods and the prices of goods. If they could get rid of it by spending it, the excess money would have at most only a temporary effect.
It's exactly the same with excess reserves. But here we need to be careful about how we define "excess reserves". The economically relevant definition is "actual stock of reserves minus desired stock of reserves". We should not define "excess reserves" as "actual stock of reserves minus legally rquired stock of reserves". The former definition works for economists in all countries, regardless of whether or not there are legal reserve requirements (Canada has none). The latter definition is only good for US lawyers.
It makes absolutely no difference whether banks make loans in the form of currency or in the form of creating demand deposits. An individual bank that makes a loan of $100 by creating a deposit of $100 will lose $100 of reserves to a second bank when the borrower spends that $100 on a bike, and the bike seller deposits the cheque in that second bank. If the bike seller will only accept currency, so the first bank swaps $100 in reserves for $100 in currency, then lends $100 currency to the borrower, the loss in reserves is immediate, rather than delayed by a day or two. But the end result is exactly the same.
Let's cut to the goddamn chase: banks lend reserves.
And the fact that banks cannot in aggregate get rid of the excess reserves is a central part of the standard textbook story of why excess reserves raise the stock of money, which creates an excess supply of money, which raises the demand for goods and the prices of goods. If banks in aggregate could get rid of reserves by lending them, the excess reserves would have at most only a temporary effect.
(I could do another post on the "needs of trade" fallacy (the idea that "interest-rate-targeting central banks supply whatever reserves are needed") in that paper, but I have already done several related posts, like this one. So I think I will drive to Wawa instead.)
"Practical men, who believe themselves to be quite exempt from any intellectual influence, are usually the slaves of some defunct economist." Yes, for example, John Maynard Keynes himself.
Your comment is true (modulo the treasury's ability to soak up dollars through taxes), but it also true for stocks or any other asset. People miss this all the time - all the stocks are always held by someone. So, next time you here a strategy that says everyone needs to rebalance, or you need to pull back from the stock market, we can't all do that. It is impossible - for everyone who is underweight stocks, someone must be overweight. This is why, in the aggregate everyone - including active management - gets the index return. Active management, by an identity no less, is a zero sum game for exactly this reason.
Posted by: Avon Barksdale | June 24, 2014 at 09:27 AM
Avon: Yep.
People in aggregate cannot sell their stocks (unless the issuers buy back those stocks). But their individual attempts to do so cause the prices of stocks to fall (the price of other things in terms of stocks to rise).
People in aggregate cannot sell their money (unless the issuers buy back that money). But their individual attempts to do so cause the prices of money to fall (the price of other things in terms of money to rise).
Banks in aggregate cannot sell their reserves (unless the central bank buys back those reserves). But their individual attempts to do so cause the prices of reserves to fall (the price of other things in terms of reserves to rise).
Posted by: Nick Rowe | June 24, 2014 at 09:56 AM
"If an individual person has excess money, he can and will get rid of it, by spending it or by lending it."
If by "money" here, you mean transaction account balances, then one of the obvious ways of getting rid of it is by lending it to the bank, i.e. putting it into a time deposit. Which does get rid of it in aggregate.
Posted by: Nick Edmonds | June 24, 2014 at 10:24 AM
When people say "banks don't lend reserves" they seem to mean 2 things
1. They technically don't lend reserves. However as soon the loaned money is spent it will likely lead to a drain on the reserves of the lending bank, that will be equivalent to them actually having lent reserves. This renders this version more of a technicality than anything very helpful in understanding the role of reserves.
2. The amount of lending in the system is determined by the CB target interest rate and not the amount of reserves. The CB will adjust the money supply to make sure banks can get the reserves they need to back current lending.
This sees a more viable justification for saying "banks don't lend reserves". I can imagine that banks may actually be looking to make loans that they know will cause a drain on their reserves below optimal levels. But this doesn't concern them because they know that at the current target rates they will be able to get the reserves and get back to optimal levels and still make a profit on the loan. I doubt if banks can totally adopt this model (it doesn't sound like it would be a profit maximizing strategy - no matter what the CB target rate is, they still need to be competing to get people to lend them money that they can lend out at a profit). But as knowledge of CB policies and the current target rate does affect bank policies to some degree (and therefor puts a bit of a wedge between reserves and lending) I don't feel comfortable totally rejecting the "banks don't lend reserves" mantra.
Posted by: Market Fiscalist | June 24, 2014 at 10:48 AM
Nick E: similarly, if a bank buys a bond from the central bank, that gets rid of reserves.
TMF: I think you are right. And sometimes they use that technicality (refusal to cut to the chase) to try to back up that second substantive (but wrong) point.
Posted by: Nick Rowe | June 24, 2014 at 11:25 AM
TMF: I would rephrase your own point like this: the demand for reserves (the desired stock of reserves) depends on current and expected future central bank policies. People who know they can always buy gas quickly at a reasonable price won't hold as much reserves of gas as would people who expect shortages and the risk of price spikes.
Posted by: Nick Rowe | June 24, 2014 at 11:30 AM
Nick, I'm so with you on comments about money "flowing into" the economy through spending. Or the idea that health-care spending (or whatever) "takes money out of the economy." Utterly incoherent.
But if money is properly conceived, the idea of money hoarding is perfectly coherent. The money conception you bruit here I think confuses money with "currency-like things." Hence the endless, fruitless imbroglios about MB, M1, divisias, etc.
The following courtesy of Jesse Livermore's brilliant understandings, which I tried to condense and riff on here:
http://www.asymptosis.com/modern-monetarist-thoughts-on-wealth-and-spending-volume-or-velocity.html
Money in the form of bonds/cash is created through deficit spending -- by the federal government and by individuals borrowing from banks that are licensed by the government to "print money" for lending.
When you use your credit card instead of your debit card, you're creating money. Pay down your debts, you're destroying it. The government and banks don't just have printing presses, they have furnaces.
But money is also created (and destroyed) by the financial markets adjusting portfolio allocations. If the markets are confidently optimistic ("animal spirits"), they shift their percentage preferences from bonds/cash to stocks, bidding up stock values. (The aggregate value of bonds/cash declines less than stocks go up.) Voila, there's more money out there. Ditto if there's more deficit spending hence more bonds/cash. Fixed portfolio allocation preferences result in stock prices being bid up.
Aside: Pace Piketty, wealth -- claims on real assets/capital -- can increase even without an increase in assets/capital. People simply think they're worth more, that there will more to claim in the future.
So the stock of money can increase through deficit spending, or increased animal spirits.
But (going all monetarist here), what about velocity? How fast does that stock of money turn over? If it turns over more slowly, that is quite properly characterized, I think, as "money hoarding." Faster turnover (at a given M) results more spending, less 'hoarding."
So how do individual decisions play out? If people are more confidently optimistic, they will:
1. Borrow more, increasing M.
2. Shift their portfolio allocations toward stocks, increasing M.
3 Spend a larger percentage of a given M each year, increasing V. (This interacts directly with #1 -- should they spend, or pay down debt?)
> People in aggregate cannot sell their money (unless the issuers buy back that money)
Issuers of many loans -- consumer, mortgage, business, etc. -- are prepared and actually required to buy back that money on demand from the borrower. We can pay off our (collective) credit-card debt at any time.
What do issuers buy that money back with? When the borrower says "I want to redeem my cash," what must the issuer provide as redemption? Retired promises, liabilities.
Unless you want to posit a perfect mechanical long-term relationship between the demand for redemptions/loans and interest rates, and a resulting perfect interest-rate-mediated counter-effect on that demand for redemptions/loans -- a relationship that is 1. logically questionable and 2. invisible, non-existent in the long-term data -- then I think you have to acknowledge that people -- yes in aggregate -- can, very simply, "sell their money."
Posted by: Steve Roth | June 24, 2014 at 11:32 AM
Mid-twentieth-century analytical philosophers came up with something called the Significant Contrast Principle. The idea was that words exist in everyday language in order to mark significant contrasts. It often happens that someone (usually a philosopher) proposes a definition of a common term (verb, adjective, common noun) according to which *everything* or *nothing* *must* fall under the term; by SCP such a definition must be erroneous. When a critic confronts a philosopher who has violated SCP with the contrast that the term actually marks, the latter's typical response is to propose a new term to mark *that* contrast, while insisting that his definition of the original terms was sound.
In your plagiarized rubbish we read: "Neither individual people nor people as a whole can 'spend' money, but individual people can and do offload their money . . . ." So 'spending' is supposed to be impossible; what people actually mean by that term can be expressed, but only by a different term: 'offload'.
Posted by: Philo | June 24, 2014 at 12:29 PM
". . . the original term," not "terms."
Posted by: Philo | June 24, 2014 at 12:30 PM
http://pragcap.com/david-andolfatto-gets-excess-reserves-and-inflation-risk-right/comment-page-1#comment-178598
Posted by: Tom Brown | June 24, 2014 at 02:43 PM
In what sense does a bank ever have more reserves than it desires? Why would their be a limit on the desired reserves of a bank?
Posted by: John Carney | June 24, 2014 at 03:00 PM
But Nick, people in aggregate can get rid of excess money. If all my friends and I pay off our student loan and mortgage debts, the aggregate money supply (deposits) will decrease, ceteris paribus. And the banks have no control over whether we want to pay off our debts.
Whereas for reserves, you're right, there's no way to decrease the amount of reserves unless the central bank decides to drain them. But the point is, an increase in reserves does not entail an increase in the money supply (because we in the aggregate could focus on paying down debts) or an increase in the price level. Those are determined by the demand for loans, which is independent of the amount of reserves, but dependent on the price of them (interest rates).
Posted by: Jared | June 24, 2014 at 03:02 PM
To put it differently, your definition of "excess reserves" makes your argument circular. Excess reserves are reserves banks want to get rid of; so banks get rid of excess reserves.
I don't see any realistic situation in which a bank would ever say: "I have too many reserves! Better find a way to lend them!"
What would possibly be the motivation for that? I guess a tax on reserves or negative interest on reserves would do the trick. But in that case, it's better for banks to contract reserves by forcing depositors to make withdrawals rather than make a loan the bank would otherwise find uneconomic.
That will increase the cash holdings of depositors but why would holding cash rather than deposits prompt any spending? If you weren't spending your deposit, you aren't spending your cash.
Likewise, capital requirements can make holding deposits unattractive. And then the same thing happens. Banks push out depositors.
A better way of looking at reserves is this: a bank with traditionally defined "excess reserves" can make more loans without either borrowing on the interbank market or running afoul of minimum reserve requirements.
The banking system, as a whole, might appear to have excess lending capacity. But this is only true if you assume there is no monetary policy offset. Yes, banks could lend so much that they'd cause unwanted inflation--but only if the Fed refused to drain the reserves. I cannot imagine a world in which this would occur.
Which is to say, its not the amount of reserves that matters but the demand for loans from credit worthy borrowers and the monetary policy of the Fed.
Posted by: John Carney | June 24, 2014 at 03:41 PM
In other words, large reserve balances have no effect at all on bank lending.
Posted by: John Carney | June 24, 2014 at 03:50 PM
Consider this quote (from https://www.richmondfed.org/publications/research/economic_brief/2010/eb_10-03.cfm):
"Suppose the banking system as a whole wanted to increase lending. At first it would be thwarted by the lack of excess reserves: Increasing loans means creating deposits, and deposits require reserves. To increase reserves, an individual bank has several options; it can sell assets, raise deposits, borrow in the interbank market, or issue securities. Although other avenues might fund some of the expansion, it seems likely that banks would want to finance long-term commercial and industrial loans in large part through deposits. But increasing deposits takes time. The bank has to offer better rates and investors only turn to deposits gradually. Thus, the policymaker has some time to pick up the signals indicating that the economy is improving..."
The author seems to be saying that normally banks are unable to quickly enlarge their loan portfolios because they must seek funding, which takes time, but when reserves are abundant this isn't the case. Hence there is a heightened risk of inflation sparked by excessive bank lending.
Agree or disagree?
Posted by: Max | June 24, 2014 at 03:50 PM
Max,
You have to follow all the moving parts. And if you do, you'll see why there isn't really a heightened risk of inflation.
A rapid expansion of lending isn't possible if you hold the supply of reserves fixed. The banks will bid up the price of reserves on the interbank market/deposit market. As reserves become more expensive, the attractiveness of certain loans will diminish. The rapid expansion will be curtailed.
The important phrase in the above paragraph is "if you hold the supply of reserves fixed." But there's no reason to do that. And, in fact, the Fed doesn't hold the supply of reserves fixed.
Instead, the Fed targets an interest rate and adjust reserve levels to hit their target.
So if the Fed is in favor of the rapid expansion of credit, it will supply new reserves to the system as needed to prevent the fed funds rate from exceeding its target. In practice, it typically doesn't need to supply very much to push rates where it wants them to go.
If the Fed doesn't want the rapid expansion to occur, it raises its target. If banks bidding for reserves naturally raises the rate to the target, the Fed doesn't need to do a thing. If necessary, the Fed drains reserves by selling assets in open market operations. The Fed could also raise reserve requirements or "anchor" excess reserves by raising paid interest on them, discouraging lending.
When banks have a large amount of reserves, the situation is exactly the same. Banks make loans they want to make, without regard to the amount of reserves. Rather, it is the price that matters. That price is affected by the quantity and demand, but the Fed has control over both because it can add quantity and demand in unlimited amounts.
In other words, what the reserve quantity theorists are missing is the monetary policy offset. Which is weird, because they are otherwise totally obsessed with monetary policy offsets.
Posted by: John Carney | June 24, 2014 at 05:03 PM
Did you just invent a new definition for spending as it relates to money? No one I know believes that when you "spend" the money disappears.
"This explains why creating money does not work to increase spending." Imagine all the "excess reserves" where created directly to the public evenly instead of to large banks/corporates through asset purchases. Spending would be much higher if the public received that money. People receive utility from consumption whereas large corporations do not. Therefore people will spend no matter what, whereas corporations wont if no investment opportunities exist.
Posted by: dannyb2b | June 24, 2014 at 05:21 PM
John Carney, you write:
"To put it differently, your definition of "excess reserves" makes your argument circular."
Hmmm, I had a similar thought elsewhere:
http://informationtransfereconomics.blogspot.com/2014/06/the-information-transfer-model.html?showComment=1403637904134#c184405280704343673
and here (at the bottom, where I define jenesaisquoishness):
http://thefaintofheart.wordpress.com/2014/06/24/halting-qe-active-monetary-asphyxiation/#comment-14500
But I was inspired by comments like this:
http://thefaintofheart.wordpress.com/2014/06/07/what-simon-wren-lewis-thinks-he-knows-is-not-true/#comment-14361
Posted by: Tom Brown | June 24, 2014 at 06:02 PM
Nick
Your comment to Avon is absolutely right:
"People in aggregate cannot sell their stocks (unless the issuers buy back those stocks). But their individual attempts to do so cause the prices of stocks to fall (the price of other things in terms of stocks to rise).
People in aggregate cannot sell their money (unless the issuers buy back that money). But their individual attempts to do so cause the prices of money to fall (the price of other things in terms of money to rise).
Banks in aggregate cannot sell their reserves (unless the central bank buys back those reserves). But their individual attempts to do so cause the prices of reserves to fall (the price of other things in terms of reserves to rise). "
Now, what IS the price of reserves? What other things are *transacted* in terms of reserves ( I say transacted and denominated, because you're a medium of exchange-er)?
Nothing, except overnight unsecured loans by a subset of financial institutions.
The price of *money*, whatever it is. is the inverse of the price level. The price of *reserves* is simply the delta between the the interest rate paid on excess reserves (IoER/ reverse repo rate etc.) and the overnight unsecured inter-bank rate (fed funds rate/ call money rate/ whatever).
And lastly, what is, operationally, a central bank on business-as-usual days? It is a monopolist on reserves. And it often has a target price for reserves. A credible monopolist can, and will, enforce its price target. And that's what central banks do.
And so, banks don't lend reserves. They really don't. Even if everything else you say is bang on true.
Posted by: Ritwik | June 24, 2014 at 06:18 PM
"To see what is wrong with that standard textbook view, we need to consider the following fundamental accounting identity:
"M = M
"The amount of money that people hold must equal the amount of money created by the banking system. You can't see "spending" anywhere in that fundamental accounting identity, can you? Therefore, people do not "spend" money!"
Not to agree or disagree with your point, Nick, but your logic is flawed.
By that logic, the conservation of energy means that nothing ever expends energy. Fires do not burn, for example. Similarly, the conservation of matter means that nobody ever gains or loses weight (mass). Similarly, the conservation of momentum means that nothing ever accelerates.
Even if the amount of money remains constant within an economic system, that does not mean that money does not circulate in that system, nor that individuals or other entities within that system do not receive or spend money.
Posted by: Min | June 24, 2014 at 06:36 PM
Nick, I was very relieved when I got to your line that reads
The above is total rubbish, of course.
SO relieved.
In the more "sensible" part of your post you wrote:
If an individual person has excess money, he can and will get rid of it, by spending it
(You actually say "by spending it or by lending it" but you also say lending is the same as spending.)
So people spend their excess money. How, then, can we tell excess money from the money people "desire to hold"? People spend that too, right?
Posted by: The Arthurian | June 24, 2014 at 09:32 PM
Nick Rowe: "The above is total rubbish, of course."
Good one, Nick! You cotched me. ;)
As for Sheard's article, you have not piqued my interest.
Posted by: Min | June 24, 2014 at 10:37 PM
"Let's cut to the goddamn chase: banks lend reserves."
By that do you mean that banks do not create money?
Doesn't that statement depend upon how your banking system is set up?
I remember hearing the author of a book about the era of wildcat banking in the U. S. (libertarian nirvana, I suppose ;)) telling about a bank in Rhode Island that issued some $600,000 in bank notes with 7 bits of a Spanish Dollar ($0.875) in the vault. What reserves did it lend?
Posted by: Min | June 24, 2014 at 10:44 PM
Is Wawa a chant-free zone?
Posted by: JKH | June 25, 2014 at 03:27 AM
Nick,
If you want to say that banks do lend reserves, who would you say they lend them to? I guess that would have to be the borrower, as it doesn't seem right to say they are loaned to the borrower's bank. But there is no sense in which the borrower owns the reserves. The borrower's bank does not hold them on the borrower's behalf, any more than it holds on my behalf cash that I deposit.
So, I guess you would have to say that if banks lend reserves, then the borrower automatically lends them back again (but maybe to a different bank). Which I suppose you could say, but is there an analogous counter-loan when non-banks lend money?
Posted by: Nick Edmonds | June 25, 2014 at 03:43 AM
Made it to North Bay. MX6 ran fine through heavy rain. I "spent" the night at Glen Garry motel (recommended). Heading towards Wawa soon. Trying to figure out my new laptop toy. Not very good at typing on it yet.
Thanks for the comments. I read them all.
John Carney: economists explain prices through demand and supply. If the price of apples is above equilibrium there is excess supply, which forces price down. Same for price of assets like houses, shares,....or money.
The Arthurian has the best critique. I did a post on that once (talking about Australian opals). In that sense (we are always getting rid of money, by spending it) the medium of exchange is different from other assets.
It's getting light. Time to get up and drive. Probably no internet for a couple of days.
Posted by: Nick Rowe | June 25, 2014 at 05:08 AM
And the fact that banks cannot in aggregate get rid of the excess reserves is a central part of the standard textbook story of why excess reserves raise the stock of money, which creates an excess supply of money, which raises the demand for goods and the prices of goods. If banks in aggregate could get rid of reserves by lending them, the excess reserves would have at most only a temporary effect.
Perhaps this is true - at least in some textbooks. But it seems to me that many, many people have over the past few years pointed to the high and stationary (or growing) reserve levels as an indication that banks are not lending or spending their money. I guess they aren't reading the textbooks.
In any case, I'm with John Carney. Where some asset is of positive value to its holder, and there is no cost to holding and accumulating an indefinitely large amount of that asset, then there is no such thing as excess amount of it. For no bank x is there a quantity of money y, such that y is the maximum amount of money x is willing to hold. This is true even if there is only one bank and x is thus identical to the entire banking system. The more money the better.
That's not to say that the increased supply of that asset can't decrease its price, if the price can go lower. But the only thing banks can really spend their money on is promises for more money. So if the price of money goes down, so does the price of the promises for money you can buy in return. The price for money is commitment to a schedule of money payments. If the market value of money goes down, so does the value of any arbitrary schedules of money payments, so there is no change in the market terms, except in the short term as the equilibrium is re-established.
Posted by: Dan Kervick | June 25, 2014 at 08:03 AM
"In what sense does a bank ever have more reserves than it desires?"
I suspect that a distinction between demand and quantity demanded needs to be made somewhere here.
Posted by: W. Peden | June 25, 2014 at 08:06 AM
Any bank can send an armored car to a Federal Reserve branch and withdraw their excess reserves as paper money. So any claim that banks don't loan out excess reserves is like saying they don't loan out paper money. While this may be technically true, it is not helpful to understanding what is going to happen.
I think it is best to view excess reserves like government debt as far as the risk of inflation and hyperinflation.
http://www.financialsense.com/contributors/vincent-cate/excess-reserves-is-like-government-debt
Posted by: Vincecate.wordpress.com | June 25, 2014 at 09:21 AM
"The fact that people cannot in aggregate get rid of the excess money is a central part of the standard story of why excess money raises the demand for goods and the prices of goods....It's exactly the same with excess reserves."
Are excess reserves really spend by banks on goods and services? Are they not used to buy bonds until the interest on the bond equals the IOR at which point banks become indifferent between holding reserve deposits or bond assets? And if excess reserves are not spend in a GDP-relevant sense how can an increase in them affect the general price level?
Posted by: Odie | June 25, 2014 at 09:45 AM
How are you defining goods in the following sentence?
"The fact that people cannot in aggregate get rid of the excess money is a central part of the standard story of why excess money raises the demand for goods and the prices of goods."
Could the "goods" be financial assets as well? Is there a mechanism for financial asset price inflation to feed into wage growth? Does the distribution of the excess money or the existing distribution of income/wealth influence whether the inflation occurs in consumable goods or financial assets?
How many transactions does it take for the price of a bar of soap to increase or decrease as a result of a change in demand? I would presume it would take many transactions. How many transactions does it take for the price of a stock to increase or decrease as a result of a change in demand? It would only take one transaction and then everyone's holdings of that stock are repriced. All of the financial asset price inflation can be undone with a handful of transactions.
Posted by: AB | June 25, 2014 at 09:50 AM
I do not get it: people can easily as aggregate reduce the amount of money (bank deposits), the banks practically cannot (reserves). That was Nick E's point above and I think Nick R. only addressed the case that _individual_ bank ("Nick E: similarly, if a bank buys a bond from the central bank, that gets rid of reserves.") can get rid of the reserves - which IMO doesn't address it at all.
Posted by: Jussi | June 25, 2014 at 09:51 AM
@Min:
But your first sentence is actually true, outside of nuclear-type interactions. Energy is indeed not expended (spent!).
What your illustrative examples refer to, however, is the notion of entropy, or disorder in a system. Closed physical systems tend towards increasing entropy, where the same quantity of energy (and mass, again outside of nuclear reactions) is rearranged into the most-disordered form over time.
Those definitions are made precise in the laws (and study) of thermodynamics, but the key insight is that in "high entropy" systems there are a lot of microsocopic ways (microstates) for the system to arrange itself yet preserve the bulk properties. It takes work to introduce order to the system, in much the same way it takes work to organize your sock drawer.
Unfortunately, there is no such tidy packaging for economics.
@Dan Kervick:
I don't see why the stories are wholly inconsistent. High-and-growing reserves, which show up as "excess" over legal requirements, can occur for one of two reasons:
The first is that banks would like to lend these reserves (making them "excess" in Nick's terminology), but they are collectively unable to increase their corresponding loan portfolios. This is exactly the practical effect of a zero lower bound on interest rates, whereby reducing rates further to increase loans would result in a negative risk-adjusted nominal rate. (Note that this also only applies to short-term rates, since bank reserves are effectively an on-demand asset; reducing long-term rates can still increase loans, but banks take on risks associated with term structures to make long-term, low-rate loans.)
The second possibility is that banks would not like to lend these reserves, making them not-excess according to Nick's terminology (but still "excess of legal requirements"). In this case, we have to consider just why the banks do not wish to lend those reserves.
The intrinsic reason for "not excess reserves" relates to the reason banks have reserves in the first place: as a hedge against credit losses. This became very important in the immediate aftermath of the credit crisis, as banks were unexpectedly exposed to counterparty risks and sudden readjustment of the risks of supposedly safe assets (namely mortgage-backed securities). Banks, understandably not wanting to fail, would necessarily and collectively seek an increase in held reserves to hedge against further shocks. Of course, that collective increase is impossible without central bank action.
The extrinsic reason for "not excess reserves" is the effect of central bank action: too-large interest on reserves. Effectively, that raises the floor of the zero lower bound up to the IOR level: a bank receiving 0.25% interest in reserves (the current US Fed level) will find it unprofitable to issue a risk-adjusted 0.2% short-term loan.
The problem of both cases of large-but-not-excess reserves is that the "not excess" part is a matter of opinion and policy. If credit risks improve or if the risk-adjusted retail loan rate materially exceeds the IOR rate, then banks suddenly are in the position of having truly excess reserves. Those in turn can be mobilized quickly as banks seek to collectively reduce reserves, perhaps sparking further credit bubbles.
Payment of IOR at a level modestly below the central bank's target rate allows banks to adjust their marginal use of reserves, but it prevents rapid mobilization of huge quantities of those reserves. A credit bubble would necessarily lower the market interest rate, but if it falls below the IOR rate banks will still curtail further loan expansion as if they were at the zero lower bound. In that way, IOR acts as a limiter on how rapidly credit can accelerate without policy intervention.
Posted by: Majromax | June 25, 2014 at 10:12 AM
"TMF: I would rephrase your own point like this: the demand for reserves (the desired stock of reserves) depends on current and expected future central bank policies. People who know they can always buy gas quickly at a reasonable price won't hold as much reserves of gas as would people who expect shortages and the risk of price spikes."
Yes, I like that way of looking at it. Would it be correct to say "current lending is a function of current reserves and expectations of future reserves" ? (where those expectations are largely set by the stance of monetary policy).
Posted by: Market Fiscalist | June 25, 2014 at 11:01 AM
@ Majromax
Thanks. :) I was aware that I was talking about entropy.
Posted by: Min | June 25, 2014 at 11:24 AM
Dan Kervick,
"For no bank x is there a quantity of money y, such that y is the maximum amount of money x is willing to hold. This is true even if there is only one bank and x is thus identical to the entire banking system. The more money the better."
You seem to me to be confusing money and wealth. Yes, everyone would like more wealth, but given your current level of wealth, would you rather hold it in the form of money, or in some other form. Personally I'd rather not hold my wealth as cash in a vault. I'd rather hold it in some form of interest-bearing asset. Same goes for banks, usually.
Posted by: Philippe | June 25, 2014 at 11:32 AM
Hi Nick,
Well, I wrote down a simple model and have concluded that you are basically correct.
http://andolfatto.blogspot.ca/2014/06/excess-reserves-and-inflation-risk-model.html
Thanks for your post, it helped set my thinking straight.
Posted by: David Andolfatto | June 25, 2014 at 12:18 PM
@Nick, serious question: Which textbook do you use in teaching macro / money?
I ask because I agree totally with your approach but in textbooks I only find obscure ISLMASAD etc. etc.
Posted by: Herbert | June 25, 2014 at 01:20 PM
People can and do spend their money, just as banks can and do lend out their money.
What you're trying to say is that in the aggregate the human race does not spend its money, or in other words, the total sum of money in existence on this planet doesn't change by virtue of one or some people spending his or their money. You might someday be able to come up with a more artful way of phrasing that, but what you're doing instead, denying that people spend money, isn't just counterintuitive, it's silly and wrong.
Posted by: Tom | June 25, 2014 at 01:54 PM
Nick said: "People in aggregate cannot sell their money (unless the issuers buy back that money)."
Jared said: "But Nick, people in aggregate can get rid of excess money. If all my friends and I pay off our student loan and mortgage debts, the aggregate money supply (deposits) will decrease, ceteris paribus. And the banks have no control over whether we want to pay off our debts."
Most loans are set up to pay back principal. A lot of loans can be paid off early.
Jared, what if you borrowed from a friend who saved demand deposits?
Jared said: "Whereas for reserves, you're right, there's no way to decrease the amount of reserves unless the central bank decides to drain them. But the point is, an increase in reserves does not entail an increase in the money supply (because we in the aggregate could focus on paying down debts) or an increase in the price level. Those are determined by the demand for loans, which is independent of the amount of reserves, but dependent on the price of them (interest rates)."
What about a currency drain?
The fed buys a bond from a levered entity. The levered entity delevers and could also save. No change in demand deposits circulating. Central bank reserves will probably have gone up.
The fed buys a bond from Warren Buffett. Buying the bond from Warren Buffett is probably not going to get him to change his mind to keep saving. He may not buy another financial asset either. No change in demand deposits circulating. Central bank reserves will probably have gone up.
Posted by: Too Much Fed | June 25, 2014 at 04:59 PM
dannyb2b seems to be the only commenter who has hinted that all this money stuff might have some relationship to the production of goods and services that people require and desire to live, rather than as anthropologically significant markers. When you state that "excess reserves raise the stock of money, which creates an excess supply of money, which raises the demand for goods and the prices of goods", you are obviously talking about financial goods, not goods in the sense of things on sale at Safeway, Saks Fifth Avenue or a Dollar Store (which does not sell actual dollars).
Living standards, of course, are related to actual goods and services, not money or financial instruments, so our era of stagnant living standards, the last 30 or so years, has not seen money created or destroyed, but rather moved from a sector which might have a positive effect on living standards into a sector which demonstrably does not. This is a lot like entropy, as discussed by Majromax. The energy is still there, it is just not in a societally useful form. You are on the right track in arguing that money is not destroyed in the ordinary cycle of things, but you and other economists need to take the next step to see why so much money has been of so little benefit.
Posted by: Kaleberg | June 25, 2014 at 11:02 PM
"The fact that people cannot in aggregate get rid of the excess money is a central part of the standard story of why excess money raises the demand for goods and the prices of goods. If they could get rid of it by spending it, the excess money would have at most only a temporary effect."
I hope JKH can verify. Borrow from a bank. Pay back all principal and interest. All of the principal demand deposits created get destroyed (***emphasis***). The interest payments cause a markup of bank equity.
A home equity line of credit (HELOC) would be a good example from personal finance. I take out a HELOC for 10 years. I can pay back the loan or almost all of the loan at any time.
Posted by: Too Much Fed | June 26, 2014 at 12:30 AM
David: Wow! Thanks.
Herbert: Canadian version of Mankiw, for intermediate macro. Good on macro, but less emphasis on money. I cannot find a money-ish text I would recommend. But maybe there are lots out there I don't know about.
All: thanks for the comments. I am stuck in Terrace Bay, north shore of Superior, because a bridge is down and HWY 17 is temporarily closed. (But it's lovely here!) Limited internet access, battery life, and brain. Will peruse them all more slowly and carefully later.
Posted by: Nick Rowe | June 26, 2014 at 12:14 PM
From:
http://www.amortization-calc.com/loan-calculator/
Loan amount of $10,000 for 1 year at 12% interest.
********************Monthly
Date *************Payment **** Interest *****Principal******Balance
Jan, 2015******* $888.49 ******$100.00 ******$788.49****$9,211.51
Feb, 2015******* $888.49 ****** $92.12 ******$796.37****$8,415.14
Mar, 2015******* $888.49 ****** $84.15 ******$804.34****$7,610.80
Apr, 2015******* $888.49 ****** $76.11 ******$812.38****$6,798.42
May, 2015******* $888.48 ****** $67.98 ******$820.50****$5,977.92
Jun, 2015******* $888.49 ****** $59.78 ******$828.71****$5,149.21
Jul, 2015******** $888.49 ****** $51.49 ******$837.00****$4,312.21
Aug, 2015******* $888.49 ****** $43.12 ******$845.37****$3,466.85
Sep, 2015******* $888.49 ****** $34.67 ******$853.82****$2,613.03
Oct, 2015******* $888.49 ****** $26.13 ******$862.36****$1,750.67
Nov, 2015******* $888.49 ****** $17.51 ******$870.98******$879.69
Dec, 2015******* $888.49 ******* $8.80 ******$879.69*********$0.00
2015 ********* $10,661.87***** $661.85***$10,000.00*********$0.00
The way the accounting people explained it to me was that the principal payments mark down both the asset (loan) and the liability (demand deposits). Demand deposits ("money") get destroyed by paying down the principal.
Posted by: Too Much Fed | June 26, 2014 at 02:15 PM
@TMF:
Was the loan amortization table really necessary? Interest is a thing, yes. It also doesn't enter into this discussion.
You're not addressing any point that Nick made. The bulk of his post dealt with spending, which is what we do at the corner store. In that case, he's fully right: the aggregate stock of money is not changed with the exchange of money for goods and services.
You're discussing loan repayments, which enters implicitly into "the other side" of M=M: by paying back a loan, you've acted to reduce the amount of money that the banking system has created.
Now, even when you're right you're still wrong. If the banking system has no excess reserves (over desired reserves), then your loan repayment will simply result in another loan being issued to the next marginal borrower, enticed by a slightly lower interest rate versus the counterfactual of keeping your loan outstanding. The net money supply created remains (in equilibrium) M, so your cash is now on someone else's balance sheet just as if they'd taken over your loan.
If the banking system does have excess reserves, then by definition it can't issue another marginal loan. In such a case, your excess cash has been transformed into additional excess reserves.
Now, I think I disagree with Nick's exact phrasing on the "hot potato effect" of excess reserves, but it's mostly an issue of time-scale. Ephemeral excess reserves caused by early repayment of my loan don't stay excess very long, so they do have a hot-potato effect. Durable excess reserves indicate that the banking system can't or won't make further loans (that is, expand bank leverage).
The "won't" part is probably okay -- it indicates that the banks are willing to hold hotter-than-previous potatoes so as to not get caught without one. Increasing reserves are an expected reaction to potential credit risks, but it still preserves the mechanism of "excess reserves" in that a marginal reserve increase is a hot potato.
The "can't" bit is the problem of the zero lower bound. In this case, the marginal reserve still can't be lent out profitably, so none of the potatoes are hot. That's bad from an economic standpoint, whereby cold potatoes are unappetizing.
Posted by: Majromax | June 26, 2014 at 02:55 PM
Majromax: "You're not addressing any point that Nick made. The bulk of his post dealt with spending, which is what we do at the corner store. In that case, he's fully right: the aggregate stock of money is not changed with the exchange of money for goods and services."
That is not what Nick is saying. At least it is not his main point. After all, that statement is the beginning of what Nick called rubbish. It is what everybody, whether they are spouting rubbish or not, accepts as true.
Posted by: Min | June 26, 2014 at 03:23 PM
By "true", I mean "given". The rubbish part is that, even if the amount of money remains the same, people do not spend money.
I am sure that Nick is objecting to the rubbish, but otherwise I am not sure what he is claiming, which is why I have asked some questions.
Posted by: Min | June 26, 2014 at 03:28 PM
Majromax,
"If the banking system creates an excess supply of money, and holds that stock of money constant, each individual person can get rid of it, but people in aggregate cannot get rid of it. It just keeps circulating back to them, as quickly as they spend it. But their individual attempts to get rid of it are what create the increased demand for goods, which will ultimately raise the prices of goods above what they would otherwise have been. The fact that people cannot in aggregate get rid of the excess money is a central part of the standard story of why excess money raises the demand for goods and the prices of goods. If they could get rid of it by spending it, the excess money would have at most only a temporary effect."
The banking system may not be in charge here. The loan terms, including repayment of principal, matter. Entities could get rid of their excess money by repaying a bank loan ("spending" on a bank loan).
Posted by: Too Much Fed | June 26, 2014 at 04:04 PM
Nick said: "If an individual person has excess money, he can and will get rid of it, by spending it or by lending it. (And "lending" means "buying an IOU from someone", so it's the same as spending.) But that just means another individual person now holds it."
Some entity could use its "excess money" to buy back its "IOU" from a bank.
Majromax said: "Now, even when you're right you're still wrong. If the banking system has no excess reserves (over desired reserves), then your loan repayment will simply result in another loan being issued to the next marginal borrower, enticed by a slightly lower interest rate versus the counterfactual of keeping your loan outstanding. The net money supply created remains (in equilibrium) M, so your cash is now on someone else's balance sheet just as if they'd taken over your loan."
What if there are not enough creditworthy entities who want to borrow?
Posted by: Too Much Fed | June 26, 2014 at 04:20 PM
Nick,
why are you going to Wawa?
Posted by: Philippe | June 26, 2014 at 05:51 PM
@TMF:
> What if there are not enough creditworthy entities who want to borrow?
Then we're at the zero lower bound, aren't we?
Posted by: Majromax | June 26, 2014 at 06:16 PM
Majromax: "If the banking system has no excess reserves (over desired reserves), then your loan repayment will simply result in another loan being issued to the next marginal borrower, enticed by a slightly lower interest rate versus the counterfactual of keeping your loan outstanding."
That is an empirical question, isn't it?
Posted by: Min | June 26, 2014 at 10:10 PM
@Min:
> That is an empirical question, isn't it?
Only insofar as markets are empirical. My statement about the marginal loan is just a longer-winded way of saying that the loan market clears, and Nick's bold statements in his post are applicable: temporary excess reserves cause a cycle of increased lending. Heck, it's even a money multiplier but we don't have to be so quantitative.
If banks have reserves in excess of their desired level, then the loan market has not cleared, and Nick's hot potato is fruitless. No matter how many steaming spuds we have, banks can't profitably extend further loans, and we're at something that looks very much like a ZLB.
I suppose the separation here between short-term disequilibrium and long-term disequilibrium is empirical, but I don't think the distinction is subtle. Loan prices (interest rates) are quite flexible, so I'd intuitively expect the loan market to clear over timescales of a few months.
Posted by: Majromax | June 27, 2014 at 09:38 AM
Addendum to the above: if it's not clear from context, I think this long-term disequilibrium is applicable to the United States.
As I understand it, the Fed is paying 0.25% interest on reserves, yet the short-term rates are at 0.01% to 0.11% for maturities as far as a year out (and 0.05%-0.1% for 1-3 month commercial paper). That more than satisfies my non-clearing requirement that the banks be unable to issue profitable loans, since the risk-free rates they can achieve are below the IOR rate.
I don't think that is applicable in Canada, however. Three-month Canadian treasury bills are a bit above 0.9%, whereas the deposit rate is 0.75%. All other things being equal, Canadian banks with excess reserves would be able to hold treasury bills instead to earn a profit, ergo they're probably not holding on to significant excess reserves.
Posted by: Majromax | June 27, 2014 at 09:52 AM
Majromax: "If the banking system has no excess reserves (over desired reserves), then your loan repayment will simply result in another loan being issued to the next marginal borrower, enticed by a slightly lower interest rate versus the counterfactual of keeping your loan outstanding."
Moi: "That is an empirical question, isn't it?"
Majromax: "Only insofar as markets are empirical. My statement about the marginal loan is just a longer-winded way of saying that the loan market clears"
It sounds like you are asserting that your statement has been empirically proven. (Bearing in mind that empirical proof is different from logical or mathematical proof.) But I find it hard to come up with an operational definition of a market clearing when nothing in the market exists before the trade. In real life there are always things that do not happen but could.
Anyway, I will not press you for empirical proof. We are both mere commenters, after all. :)
Posted by: Min | June 28, 2014 at 10:09 AM
Analogy of what is being critiqued:
...."To see what is wrong with that standard textbook view, we need to consider the following fundamental accounting identity:
...."M = M
...."The amount of money that people hold must equal the amount of money created by the banking system. You can't see "spending" anywhere in that fundamental accounting identity, can you? Therefore, people do not "spend" money!"
Now, the equation should really be M1 = M0, or the like, because the point is that people do not create money by spending it, so that the resulting amount of money, M1 is equal to the previous amount of money, M0. Now, OC, the BS comes with redefining the verb, "spend". The point is that banks create money, not people.
There is another problem, too, however. A couple of nights ago I went out and bought dinner for $20, paying, not with money, but with a credit card. The dinner was paid for by money created by the bank in response to my card charge. So in that case, M1 > M0. Accounting identity indeed! We can also view that as my creating money. I did not do so myself, but because of my agreement with the bank issuing the credit card, they did it at my behest.
Now, in the analogy:
....'Basically, I just changed his "banks" to "people", his "lend" to "spend", and his "reserves" to "money".'
OK, R1 = R0, because banks do not create reserves. But what about that analogy between spending and lending? People do not create the money they spend, unless we count using credit cards and such.
...."(And "lending" means "buying an IOU from someone", so it's the same as spending.)"
Whoa, Nellie! Thet's true if people make loans, because people do not create the money that they spend (as long as M1 = M0). But the analogy does not carry over to banks, because they do create the money that they lend, even if R1 = R0. (Under our current system, OC.) Lending by banks does not simply mean buying an IOU, it also means creating the money to do so. This is uncontroversial, right?
...."Let's cut to the goddamn chase: banks lend reserves."
Banks do not create reserves themselves, right? R1 = R0. Well, if banks simply lend reserves, why in hell do they create money?
Posted by: Min | June 28, 2014 at 10:45 AM
"banks lend reserves"
Needs to be defined.
Try this scenario.
Run the model with only one commercial bank. Are reserves being lent?
Posted by: Too Much Fed | June 28, 2014 at 02:59 PM
Run the model with only one person. Is money being spent?
Posted by: Philippe | June 28, 2014 at 04:50 PM
Philippe, there will be big differences between a one person economy and a one commercial bank economy.
Posted by: Too Much Fed | June 28, 2014 at 05:46 PM
Majromax said: "Then we're at the zero lower bound, aren't we?"
What if a bank decided to do something like "QE"?
Posted by: Too Much Fed | June 28, 2014 at 05:50 PM
Nick, you've written a lot of good posts on this subject, this is another one. A question I still have (that I hope you'll address in future posts) is this: Your line of reasoning (with which I concur) is used to justify models assuming that saving drives investment. For example, the Solow model is frequently used to "demonstrate" what would happen if the government implements policies that encourage more household saving. The "answer" is that this would make us all better off in the long run (assuming the current capital stock is below the "golden rule" level) because it would increase investment. Do decisions by economic agents about how much to "save" (as opposed to decisions about how much to borrow for investment purposes) matter all that much if the central bank is targeting inflation? Economics students are repeatedly told that more "saving" leads to lower interest rates and thus more investment and a larger capital stock. Is this so? (I'm referring to long-term trends in saving as opposed to short-term fluctuations). Thank you.
Posted by: Mark | June 28, 2014 at 07:38 PM
Would be better to tax the rich and redistribute the wealth when we have less than full employment.... but the rich won't let that happen.... they control tax laws.. they hoard and hide....and so we are left with printing money.......
You are saying that we are facing the risk that money in the hands of the wealthy will become a "high multiplier" place?
We can only wish
Posted by: djb | June 29, 2014 at 08:58 AM
Mr. Rowe, much of you write here is correct -- and very clear. But there are several little points which are wrong. Others have already addressed several of them better than I could. I apologize for the length of this.
One point is key for understanding what's going on.
You write:
"(And "lending" means "buying an IOU from someone", so it's the same as spending.) "
Lending does mean "buying an IOU from someone".
However, *IOUs are a substitute for money*. If an IOU is tradeable and liquid, it actually *is* money. So this is not the same as spending.
This is essentially how money is created by private banks and other entities. You know this. These IOUs are bank-created money (or, alternativey, they are causing a drop in demand for government money). This means that even with constant "government money", the effective money stock isn't constant (or, alternatively, the demand is affected by the creation of IOUs).
Perhaps your January explanation was the better one, since it seems clearer:
http://worthwhile.typepad.com/worthwhile_canadian_initi/2013/01/two-extreme-fiscalmonetary-worlds.html
"...The government in the second, monetary world, has two degrees of freedom. It can choose how many liabilities to sell, and it can choose the rate of interest it pays on those liabilities.
"The government in the real world is a combination of those two extremes, and it can choose what combination it is. That gives it three degrees of freedom. It can choose how many liabilities to sell. It can choose what combination of liabilities to sell. And it can choose what rate of interest to pay on its monetary liabilities. Because money is different from all other assets, financial or otherwise."
I do have one dispute: I deny that there is an actual third degree of freedom. Effectively, I believe we are in "monetary world" in all the countries which haven't "dollarized" or joined the Euro. In short, T-bills or gilts are treated as money. Very large denomination money, but money.
Forget the sort of bonds which are not treated as money for now; they are not relevant.
There is red money (bank-issued money) and green money (government-issued money). The government has two degrees of freedom: quantity of money and interest rate given on money.
The commercial banks also have two degrees of freedom. They can adjust the rate of interest they offer to pay on "red money", which changes people's preference between "red money" and "green money". The banks cannot usually offer a lower rate of interest on red money than the government offers on green money (but sometimes they can, if they can claim that depositing in their bank is "safer" than holding piles of cash under your mattress). People's preference between "red money" and "green money" is not just determined by the interest rate, it's also determined by how irresponsible the recent behavior of the banks has been.
Nobody refuses "red money" -- checks, for example, are "red money", as are debit cards. Nobody stops to check whether the bank issuing the check is solvent (well, not anymore, they used to).
But the banks can also determine how much "red money" to offer! This gives them a second degree of freedom. It is *this* degree of freedom which we generally attempt to regulate, generally through abstruse and baroque methods involving "reserve requirements", "capital requirements" and so on and so forth. For the sake of my argument, imagine a country where the bank regulators are out to lunch and routinely rubberstamp anything including completely fraudulent accounting. (We'll call it the "US".) Here, it is clear that the banks have this second degree of freedom.
The amount of "red money" which is *actually supplied* depends also on the demand for it, which is also determined by the *risk taking profile of the (relatively) wealthy*.
Thank you for helping me clarify my thoughts; the January entry is particularly clear.
I hope this helps you clarify yours; the main oversight in most of the stuff I've read by you has always been bank-created money (red money) and the weird effects it has on the economy. Since the role of bank-created money -- and its *demonetization* as people suddenly decided that money market funds weren't a medium of exchange (they were on a Monday, they weren't on a Tuesday) -- is essential to the understanding the crash of 2008, I think incorporating this concept would probably assist your work.
As others have noted, it is an empirical fact that bank loan departments -- at least in the US, in the 21st century -- do not pay attention to reserve or capital levels when they make loans. Lending supply volume is not dependent on reserves in any sense, and banks strive to make it as large as possible given the bank's chosen interest rate. If the loans they issue cause the bank to have a shortage of government money, the bank simply knocks on the discount window and the Federal Reserve shovels some more government money into it. This is the entire discount window policy.
(Banks can choose their interest rate on loans in thee short term, determined by desired profit margins. In the medium term it is determined by competition with other banks -- or cartel arrangements.)
If borrowing at the discount window causes the bank to become insolvent, well, frankly in my hypothetical NO-REGULATOR world of the US, this has no effect at all; the bank continues operating and getting free money shovelled at it; the bank-issued money (deposits, commercial paper, etc.) is still treated as good money, etc. I believe we're watching this happen right now in the US.
Only if there is a threat of shutdown by the regulator (the FDIC or one of the other ones in the US) is there a run on the bank and demonetization of its deposits.
This gets back to Min's comment about the "bank in Rhode Island that issued some $600,000 in bank notes with 7 bits of a Spanish Dollar ($0.875) in the vault."
We also have shadow banks, like the money market funds. They *don't* have access to the discount window, so they can be demonetized much much faster when they run out of government money and par convertibility becomes impossible. They depend on a supply of reserves to avoid bank runs.
In any case, banks issue loans without regard to reserves. They deliver on the loans partly by actually printing banknotes (in the 19th century... or some Scottish banks), and partly by printing money in the form of checks ("here's your loan, the money is in your deposit account"). When forced to, they issue government currency; if they run out of it, they go to the Fed to get more currency, which the Fed promises to give to them. In order to pay less in interest to the Fed, they convince depositors to give them government money in exchange for "red money" (bank deposits).
Market Fiscalist describes this view, and it is correct:
"2. The amount of lending in the system is determined by the CB target interest rate and not the amount of reserves. The CB will adjust the money supply to make sure banks can get the reserves they need to back current lending."
The second sentence is simply an empirical fact about central bank policy. It is debatable whether the amount of lending in the system is determined by the CB target interest rate, but as long as there's a discount window, it is certainly *not* determined by the amount of reserves.
There are two different types of banks: those which are backed by a discount window and those which aren't (like the money market funds). They have different dynamics and different behavior, because the former don't need reserves and the latter do. Both types can and do print money.
I wouldn't mind seeing a really coherent stock-flow model of the banking system, including both types of banks, and separate elements for rich people and poor people. I've never seen one. The key number which matters for the macroeconomy is the flow of money available to *the 99%*, because that's what determines *productive activity*, purchase of stuff like food and cars. This is determined by a lot of things including willingness to borrow by the 99% and creditworthiness of the 99%.
At the moment we have high stocks of money held by the 1% and very low stocks accessible to the 99%. The maldistribution makes a lot of things happen which seem impossible in models which assume a single uniform representative individual.
Posted by: Nathanael | June 29, 2014 at 01:11 PM
Min said: "There is another problem, too, however. A couple of nights ago I went out and bought dinner for $20, paying, not with money, but with a credit card. The dinner was paid for by money created by the bank in response to my card charge. So in that case, M1 > M0. Accounting identity indeed! We can also view that as my creating money. I did not do so myself, but because of my agreement with the bank issuing the credit card, they did it at my behest."
Min, do you think demand deposits are both medium of account (MOA) and medium of exchange (MOE)?
Min, what do you think of this description of your transaction?
Min balance sheet: create a new bond that is both your asset and your liability
Bank balance sheet: create new demand deposits that are both the bank's asset and the bank's liability
Asset swap the bond for the demand deposits to your credit card account (similar to a checking account). The demand deposits become your asset. The bond becomes the bank's asset.
Asset swap the demand deposits for the food.
Posted by: Too Much Fed | June 30, 2014 at 12:32 AM
Too Much Fed: "Min, do you think demand deposits are both medium of account (MOA) and medium of exchange (MOE)?"
First, I think that money is a fuzzy concept, in the technical sense. That's why we have M0, M3, etc.
IIUC, medium of account is anything denominated in terms of the standard unit of account. Last time I looked, my demand deposits were denominated in US Dollars.
Posted by: Min | June 30, 2014 at 12:36 PM
"IIUC, medium of account is anything denominated in terms of the standard unit of account."
Min, I agree with this part at this link.
http://worthwhile.typepad.com/worthwhile_canadian_initi/2012/10/medium-of-account-vs-medium-of-exchange/comments/page/1/#comments
"[Update: just to clarify terminology: in my model, gold is the medium of account; and (say) an ounce of gold is the unit of account.]"
Nick talks somewhat about fixing prices involving MOA and MOE, but I am not sure I agree with all there.
Posted by: Too Much Fed | July 02, 2014 at 12:08 AM
O/T: Any macro types want to take up this challenge?
http://informationtransfereconomics.blogspot.com/2014/07/a-challenge-to-macroeconomists.html
Posted by: Tom Brown | July 02, 2014 at 05:10 PM
Nick,
No-one has ever said that lending does not result in reserve movements. But in my work I separate out lending and settlement, whereas you conflate the two. Lending itself DOES NOT result in reserve movements. It is the drawdown of the loan that does.
As an example, suppose I obtain funding from the bank to pay for a new kitchen. I borrow that money in advance of the work being done (because I need to know that I can). But I don't have to pay the installer until the work is completed. During the installation period, therefore, the funds sit in my deposit account. The loan has been made, but the associated reserve movement is several days or weeks later.
Now suppose that during the installation period, my wages are paid into the same account. When I pay my kitchen installer, is the money that I pay him from the loan or from my wages? You don't know. There is absolutely no way of distinguishing between these two kinds of "money". The drawdown of a loan is indistinguishable from any other sort of deposit withdrawal. People withdrawing funds from their deposit accounts - i.e. spending money - causes reserve movements: that effect is exactly the same whether the money in the account is lent to them by the bank or paid to them by their employer. So for a bank to get rid of excess reserves, it could lend, or it could encourage its depositors to withdraw (spend) the money that comes into their accounts from other sources. To a bank, they are the same thing.
To say that banks "lend reserves" is therefore looking at only one part of what banks do. Banks are deposit-takers and payment agents, too, and these functions ALSO cause reserve movements. There is WAAAY too much focus on lending and not nearly enough on what else banks do.
Not all loans are drawn, of course: refinancing loans, for example, where a bank is simply rolling over an existing loan, do not generate reserve movements. More problematically (for your argument), if a bank makes a loan which the customer then spends by transferring the funds electronically to another customer at the same bank, there is no movement of reserves. In this case, the bank has not in any sense "lent out" reserves. It has a new loan and a new deposit on its books, but its reserve position is exactly the same. Obviously the more concentrated the banking sector, the fewer reserve movements there will be: if there were only one bank, there would be no reserve movements at all, but that wouldn't mean the bank wasn't lending or people weren't spending. Reserve movements in a highly concentrated banking system such as that in the UK (and that in Canada) tell us very little about the lending behaviour of banks or the spending behaviour of their customers.
Posted by: Frances Coppola (@Frances_Coppola) | July 21, 2014 at 04:34 AM