Alone again or, just me and the money multiplier, against the world of trendy sophisticates who have put aside such childish things. It brings out the reactionary contrarian in me. And the world needs more reactionary contrarians, to help provide negative feedback against the faddish bubble multiplier of popular theory.
There are two multipliers we teach in first year: the money multiplier; and the "keynesian" (Hawtreyan?) multiplier. Both are set aside as embarrassing reminders of childhood. Let me defend them both. They have a lot in common.
Most of economics is about negative feedback processes. An increased demand for apples creates an initial excess demand for apples. But that in turn causes the price of apples to rise, which reduces quantity demanded and increases quantity supplied, eliminating the initial excess demand for apples. And the equilibrium change in quantity demanded is smaller than the original change in quantity demanded.
The money multiplier, and the keynesian multiplier, are rare examples of positive feedback processes. The equilibrium increase in money supplied is bigger than the original increase in money supplied. The equilibrium increase in output demanded is bigger than the original increase in output demanded.
The central puzzle of (short run) macroeconomics is to explain why market economies have fluctuations in the volume of trade. It is hard to identify shocks large enough to explain the trade cycle. Real Business Cycle Theory has tried, and in my opinion failed, to do just this. It would seem natural to look for positive feedback processes to help us understand why large fluctuations might result from small shocks. If the multipliers are large enough, the shocks might be too small to see. Fussing about whether the magnitudes of those multipliers are "stable" (unchanging over time) is of secondary concern. What matters is that those magnitudes are bigger than one. The "instability" of the magnitude of a positive feedback process can make that multiplier even more important in explaining fluctuations. We can ignore stuff that never changes.
You can't see the keynesian multiplier in New Keynesian models. That's because they have hidden it, or refused to look at it. But it's still there, in the Euler equation, and it's larger than ever. The marginal propensity to consume out of permanent disposable income is one, and so the keynesian multiplier is infinite in New Keynesian models. It's so big the New Keynesians have to assume it away, by turning into "classical" economists, and assuming (the representative agent expects) an automatic tendency towards "full employment" (aka the natural rate), even though nothing in their models justifies that ad hoc assumption, just to keep permanent income pinned down by the supply-side Phillips Curve.
Does permanent income determine permanent consumption, or does permanent consumption determine permanent income? Yes. As individuals, and in aggregate, we decide how much to save and invest, and our decisions affect our permanent income. But one person's spending is another person's income, and it is not unreasonable to ask, as Keynes asked, what, if anything, ensures that our (permanent) desired aggregate spending is sufficient to equal our (permanent) desired aggregate income? What, if anything, might adjust to ensure that Say's Law holds? And the answer is not "the rate of interest", because the rate of interest is a relative price, that only affects the demand and supply of present goods relative to future goods. It is a fallacy of composition to assume that, since the right rate of interest in each individual period can ensure demand equals supply in that individual period, therefore the right rate of interest in all periods can ensure that demand equals supply in all periods.
(And please don't be a knuckle-dragger and think of the keynesian multiplier as the fiscal policy multiplier. It is as much a monetary policy multiplier as a fiscal policy multiplier, and it's not even a purely policy multiplier. It multiplies anything that gets the ball rolling.)
New Keynesians adopted the monetarist tendency towards full employment, but they threw out the monetary forces that might actually get us there, and lost their own Keynesian heritage in forgetting Keynes' fundamental question to which the monetary baby was the answer.
Keynes' question only makes sense in a monetary exchange economy, where people both buy and sell all other goods for the medium of exchange. Another way to ask Keynes' fundamental question is to ask: "what, if anything, ensures there can never be an excess demand for the medium of exchange?" Because if there is an excess demand for the medium of exchange, then people will want to buy fewer goods than they want to sell.
It is no accident that New Keynesians deleted Keynes' fundamental question from their models, and deleted the medium of exchange from their models too. The two deletions are the same. Yes, if you ignore money, and assume market-clearing in future markets, then getting the right relative price in the current market (the right rate of interest) is all you need to get market-clearing in the current market.
The demand and supply of the medium of exchange matters. Central banks produce a medium of exchange, and commercial banks produce a medium of exchange too. If people can buy and sell goods using either media of exchange, and if excess demands for media of exchange matter, it makes sense to ask what determines the demands and supplies of both media of exchange.
"Banks create money!" chants the cultist. Yes they do. And one of the things the textbook money multiplier teaches the first year students is precisely that. An initial creation of money by the central bank results in a much larger equilibrium amount of money created by the banking system. Where did that extra money come from? From the commercial banks, of course. And commercial banks create that money despite each individual bank only lending out money that has been deposited in that bank, as long as they have less than 100% desired reserve-deposit ratios.
"Loans create deposits!" chants the cultist. Yes, they do. And one of the things the textbook multiplier teaches the first year students is precisely that. If the commercial banks did not expand their loans, they would create no new money on top of what the central bank created. But what the textbook also reminds us is that an individual commercial bank that creates a deposit by making a loan will very likely lose that same deposit to another bank when the borrower spends the loan and the cheque gets deposited in a different bank. It is exactly as if the individual bank had made the loan by giving the borrower central bank currency, which then gets spent and deposited in a different bank. The textbook cuts directly to the chase scene, which the cultist never gets to. Because the individual bank's incentive to make an extra loan is what matters, unless you assume all commercial banks collude to maximise joint profits, knowing that they are simply transferring base money between themselves when deposits get transferred between themselves.
And commercial banks, neither individually nor collectively, can create loans, unless they can persuade people to hold their deposits and not hold central bank money instead. Because they promise to redeem their deposit money for central bank money at a fixed exchange rate.
Is the stock of money exogenous or endogenous? Yes. The stock of money depends on stuff that is assumed exogenous in the model, like the inflation target, and various shocks. In that sense the stock of money is (trivially) endogenous, because it will change when that exogenous stuff changes. But that does not mean the stock of money responds only to changes in the demand for money, so there can never be an excess supply or demand for money and we can ignore the supply side. Money, as medium of exchange, is traded in all markets, and just because there is neither excess demand nor supply of money in one market does not mean it cannot be in excess demand or supply in all other markets. And the medium of exchange is not like refrigerators, because we buy money in order to sell it again, not just to hold it. Suppliers of money, unlike suppliers of refrigerators, can "force" us to buy more money than we want to hold, because each buys it planning to sell it again to someone else. And that excess supply of money causes P and/or Y to increase until the quantity of money demanded adjusts to equal the quantity supplied. Say's Law, paradoxically, only applies to money itself. The supply of money creates its own demand.
(And please don't be a knuckle-dragger and assume the money multiplier refers to the multiplier effect of an initial decision by the central bank only. Yes, the textbook usually illustrates the money multiplier with an example where the initial shock comes from the central bank, just as it usually illustrates the keynesian multiplier with an example where the initial shock comes from fiscal policy. But the money multiplier, just like the keynesian multiplier, multiplies anything that gets the ball rolling.)
How big is the money multiplier? Well, that depends, on many things. Most importantly, it depends on what the central bank is targeting. If the central bank is targeting a fixed rate of interest (no central bank in its right mind would do this, but let's just suppose), the money multiplier is infinite. Just like the keynesian multiplier in New Keynesian models. Some initial shock causes one bank to expand loans and deposits, which causes other banks to expand their loans and deposits too, and the central bank expands base money as the demand for reserves + currency expands, and so on, and the ball keeps rolling until something causes it to stop. And the only thing we ought to rely on to bring the process to a stop is the central bank itself, because it is more concerned with some vaguely sensible target like inflation or NGDP, and realises that sort of target is incompatible with a permanently fixed interest rate target and "supplying base money on demand", as the cultists say.
The two positive feedback processes in the first year textbook are very closely connected. Both multipliers are infinite when the central bank targets a rate of interest and everything just scales up across markets and time-periods. Providing the right policy answer to Keynes' fundamental question requires the central bank to not allow everything to scale up. A good central bank would ensure we never observe either multiplier process in action in the real world. If we observe random shocks to government spending creating a keynesian multiplier process we know the central bank has failed. If we observe random shocks to base money creating a money multiplier process we know the central bank has failed. But the central bank needs to know its enemies to ensure they never appear in the data. This is Milton Friedman's Thermostat.
"commercial banks create that money despite each individual bank only lending out money that has been deposited in that bank"
This defines "deposit" too narrowly. A commercial bank can issue 100 checking account dollars in exchange for nothing but a "deposit" of the borrower's $100 IOU, or a "deposit" of a $100 government bond (just like central banks do).
Posted by: Mike Sproul | March 30, 2014 at 12:02 PM
Nick,
Even a quasi-knuckle-dragger like me can see that this is a brilliant post.
Comments:
“But what the textbook also reminds us is that an individual commercial bank that creates a deposit by making a loan will very likely lose that same deposit to another bank when the borrower spends the loan and the cheque gets deposited in a different bank. It is exactly as if the individual bank had made the loan by giving the borrower central bank currency, which then gets spent and deposited in a different bank.”
That is true and it is the type of thing that the cultist chanters either conveniently or ignorantly ignore. The overarching issue is really the effective differentiation of banking system behavior versus individual bank behavior – overcoming a sort of fallacy of composition in thinking things through. System loan and deposit creation is an expansion without a necessary net system reserve cause or effect. But individual bank loan creation typically results in a funding requirement including a requirement for reserves at the margin – because of your type of scenario.
I did a post on this sort of qualification. I differentiate between system loan and deposit creation versus the turbulence of competition for an existing deposit base, following that creation:
http://monetaryrealism.com/loans-create-deposits-in-context/
That said, I would still differentiate between the interpretation of the supply of currency and that of the supply of bank reserve balances. I think your overall theory works better for the supply of currency than the supply of reserve balances.
I think you move into very unconventional territory:
“And please don't be a knuckle-dragger and assume the money multiplier refers to the multiplier effect of an initial decision by the central bank only. Yes, the textbook usually illustrates the money multiplier with an example where the initial shock comes from the central bank, just as it usually illustrates the keynesian multiplier with an example where the initial shock comes from fiscal policy. But the money multiplier, just like the keynesian multiplier, multiplies anything that gets the ball rolling.”
Can you elaborate? You’re talking here about an extension of or maybe something quite different than the “required reserve multiplier” aren’t you? It almost sounds like you’re talking about something that would be unimpeded by the conventional textbook mathematics of the required reserve multiplier. I.e. more consistent with endogenous money liberation. It also sounds like something that could be quite consistent with the view that bank animal spirits in lending correspond to improving capital positions in the process – or at least not inconsistent with that. It might help to be much more specific about this framework if it is a real departure from the “required reserve multiplier” thinking – or maybe you already have in a previous post. Or maybe I just don't understand your point.
Side question:
The Keynesian multiplier doesn’t assume anything specifically or explicitly about credit and money creation, does it? It could work in (stretched) theory through velocity alone couldn't it?
Posted by: JKH | March 30, 2014 at 12:19 PM
Great post !
Of course both multipliers work together and are at the heart of the story of how money affects the economy.
Someone gives me $1000 of newly printed money. I spend some, I keep some in my wallet, and I put some in my bank account. The two multipliers then explain the series of flows within thew banking system and the rest of thee economy that continue until all the new money is either in someone's wallet or kept as bank reserves. They also help explain how prices and output have adjusted.
I am not certain of much in economics but I'm pretty sure this multiplier story is not too far away from what actually happens in the real world.
The "endogenous money" crowd like to focus on one bit of the story - the bit where banks create new loans and thereby increase the supply of broad money. They claim this undermines the whole multiplier story. Technically banks really do increase broad money when they issue loans but to focus on this above everything else in the story is to fail to see the woods for the trees.
The one danger with the multiplier story is possibly that you may forget (or simplify in your model) that as well as changes in the money supply there can be changes in other things (such as the ratios of money in people's wallet to spending and to the money they keep in the bank, banks reserve policies etc) that will change the values of the multipliers. If these other things are too volatile then the multiplier story may stop making so much sense.
Posted by: The Market Fiscalist | March 30, 2014 at 12:34 PM
Mike: let me rephrase it like this: "*Even if* each individual bank only lends out money that has been deposited in that bank, commercial banks create money."
JKH: thanks!
You are very far from a knuckle-dragger.
(I feel a little guilty using that term in this post. My visor was down, and I was swinging my sword alone, defending the truth beauty and usefulness of my fair multiplier maidens, against the hordes attacking from all directions....)
One example of an initial money multiplier shock would come from the central bank. Or it could be someone who decides to hold less currency and more deposits. Or it could be an individual bank that decides to make more loans and hold fewer reserves. Or other shocks I have forgotten. Just different ways of getting the same ball to start rolling. And the same ball can also roll in reverse, of course, like in a recession.
"The Keynesian multiplier doesn’t assume anything specifically or explicitly about credit and money creation, does it?"
It doesn't. It is silent on the question. But I think it can only be understood in tandem with some sort of money multiplier, as TMF says. Two sides of the same coin.
TMF: thanks!
"The one danger with the multiplier story is possibly that you may forget (or simplify in your model) that as well as changes in the money supply there can be changes in other things (such as the ratios of money in people's wallet to spending and to the money they keep in the bank, banks reserve policies etc) that will change the values of the multipliers."
Those things definitely need to be remembered. But above all else, we need to remember how the central bank responds, because that is our policy lever on the whole multiplier process.
Posted by: Nick Rowe | March 30, 2014 at 04:01 PM
Nick, you are one tough reactionary contrarian/curmudgeon, defiantly shaking your fist at googly-eyed "cultists" and the upstart sneering and "trendy sophisticates" alike! Hahaha :D
I followed about half that... the money multiplier half. My goal is to one day understand the other half too.
Question: you mention Keynes' "fundamental question" and a different way to state it, but I don't see that you mentioned the common/original way to state it, did you?
Also, one comment about this:
"And commercial banks create that money despite each individual bank only lending out money that has been deposited in that bank, as long as they have less than 100% desired reserve-deposit ratios."
This ignores the idea that a depositor can be induced to purchase a time deposit (or even bank equity) with his checkable deposit, thus eliminating the constraint in part or in whole.
Assuming again that there are only demand deposits: you are only covering a central bank "shock" in which a deposit starts at an initial bank. It could instead start from central bank money capital (and zero deposits): say a bunch of investors pooled their cash to start a new bank starting off with $0 in deposits. Then the 100% reserve requirement is not an upper bound: the requirement could be > 100% and the bank could still create deposits through lending. Say the initial capital was $100 and the reserve requirements was 200%, then the bank could create $50 in checkable deposits.
I realize you didn't use the term "reserve requirement" but I'm imagining that's one way to interpret "desired reserve-deposit ratios."
Also thanks for your response at Glasner's (to my question), and in case you didn't see it, he responded to your latest there.
Posted by: Tom Brown | March 30, 2014 at 04:54 PM
The money "multiplier" simply tells us the limit of money creation by the commercial banks, given their reserves. In itself it is not sufficient to tell us how much money will actually be created.
Posted by: Min | March 30, 2014 at 05:12 PM
Tom: here is Keynes' original way to state his question: "But one person's spending is another person's income, and it is not unreasonable to ask, as Keynes asked, what, if anything, ensures that our (permanent) desired aggregate spending is sufficient to equal our (permanent) desired aggregate income? What, if anything, might adjust to ensure that Say's Law holds?"
(I just stuck the words "permanent" in there.)
"This ignores the idea that a depositor can be induced to purchase a time deposit (or even bank equity) with his checkable deposit, thus eliminating the constraint in part or in whole."
Yep, and I was right to ignore that. Because that is just banks acting like non-bank financial intermediaries. Anyone can borrow money and lend it again, without creating money. I can do that myself.
A 100% reserve bank cannot create money. It can only transform money from one form (currency) into another form (demand deposits).
"I realize you didn't use the term "reserve requirement" but I'm imagining that's one way to interpret "desired reserve-deposit ratios.""
No, you must not interpret it like that. It is the desired reserve ratio that matters. Required reserve ratios only matter because they influence desired reserve ratios.
Posted by: Nick Rowe | March 30, 2014 at 05:23 PM
Min: no it doesn't. You are giving it that "American" interpretation, as the reciprocal of the *required* reserve ratio. And even then, it does not tell us an upper bound, unless initially the desired reserve ratio was equal to the required reserve ratio (it won't be), and there is no currency drain, and the central bank holds the base constant.
Posted by: Nick Rowe | March 30, 2014 at 05:29 PM
Nick,
What's your definition/concept of "desired reserves" - including reference to the relationship of desired reserves to statutorily required reserves and existing excess reserves?
(institutional thickets moment)
Posted by: JKH | March 30, 2014 at 06:07 PM
"The money multiplier, and the keynesian multiplier, are rare examples of positive feedback processes. The equilibrium increase in money supplied is bigger than the original increase in money supplied. The equilibrium increase in output demanded is bigger than the original increase in output demanded."
I don't think so. Gain is not a sufficient criterion for feedback. The money multiplier is an example of gain (with negative feedback, if you like, in the textbook picture).
The formula for negative feedback is closedLoopGain = openLoopGain / (1 + feedback * openLoopGain). With no feedback, obviously, openLoopGain = closedLoopGain
With positive feedback, The + in the denominator would be a - and closedLoopGain would go to infinity until it hit some other constraint. Positive feedback is almost always unstable (exceptions are unusual, complicated and generally to be avoided).
Of course in real systems, things get more complicated, but rarely more stable. Under certain conditions, even negative feedback systems can be unstable (c.f. phase margin and gain margin).
Posted by: Peter N | March 30, 2014 at 06:09 PM
"Anyone can borrow money and lend it again, without creating money. I can do that myself."
Cute. An amusing riff on:
"everyone can create money; the problem is to get it accepted". (Hyman Minsky, Stabilizing an Unstable Economy. Yale University Press, New Haven and London.)
Posted by: Peter N | March 30, 2014 at 06:19 PM
Mike Sproul: well put! That sentence bothered me too, but I let it go because I couldn't state my objection as clearly as you did. Nick's fix is acceptable to me.
Posted by: Tom Brown | March 30, 2014 at 07:25 PM
Peter N: Also well put!... that sentence of Nick's also bothered me a bit (but I was too lazy/not-clever-enough to think through a coherent objection)! Did you study feedback control systems in school too? (that was my major).
Posted by: Tom Brown | March 30, 2014 at 07:30 PM
Peter N: closedLoopGain = forwardLoopGain/(1 + forwardLoopGain) with negative feedback. If we're just talking scaler gain blocks here (no integrators or differentiators or delays) then if forwardLoopGain > 0, then 0 < closedLoopGain < forwardLoopGain. If we have positive feeback then closedLoopGain = forwardLoopGain/(1 - forwardLoopGain) and if forwardLoopGain is on (0,1), then 0 < forwardLoopGain < closedLoopGain, with closedLoopGain going to infinity as forwardLoopGain goes to 1. However forwardLoopGain can be > 1. So actually with simple gain blocks, positive feedback is OK here, and can produce a stable gain > 1. But if we have a characteristic polynomial in forwardLoopGain, then you'll be unstable if the roots of 1-forwardLoopGain are not in the open left half plane. (assuming this system is well described by a LTI approximation, which it probably isn't).
Posted by: Tom Brown | March 30, 2014 at 08:05 PM
... when you wrote "feedback" in the denominator did you mean "unit delay" (i.e. Z^-1)? as in a discrete time system? If we assume we're talking about a discrete time system and there's a unit delay in the feedback path, then the characteristic polynomial of the closed loop system is 1-forwardLoopGain*(Z^-1) with positive feedback which is equivalent to Z-forwardLoopGain (regarding roots). And thus if forwardLoopGain is a real scaler with magnitude >= 1, then we have a root outside the unit circle, and the system is unstable, but with smaller magnitude forwardLoopGains it's stable. I think I did that all correct! Let me know if I got it wrong there.
Posted by: Tom Brown | March 30, 2014 at 08:20 PM
... the upshot is nick, you're not necessarily unstable with positive feedback and in fact that could give you a stable steady state gain higher than the forward loop.
Posted by: Tom Brown | March 30, 2014 at 08:41 PM
... as if you cared. Lol.
Posted by: Tom Brown | March 30, 2014 at 08:49 PM
Nick Rowe:
"You are giving [the money multiplier] that "American" interpretation, as the reciprocal of the *required* reserve ratio."
Thanks, Nick. Definition, please?
Posted by: Min | March 30, 2014 at 10:13 PM
JKH and Min: "desired reserves" is that level of reserves (or ratio of reserves to deposits) that commercial banks *choose* to keep, taking into account legally required reserves, liquidity risk, etc.
E.g. in the 1930's, banks chose to keep much higher levels of reserves than were legally required, to provide a buffer zone before they would be forced to call in loans in the event of a run to keep above the legal minimum.
Quantity of reserves demanded.
Posted by: Nick Rowe | March 30, 2014 at 10:20 PM
Tom Brown,
So much for trying to keep it simple. For time stepped systems, z transforms are the natural approach. Though the standard model isn't a filter, the treatment of stability is similar, once you do some tricks to reduce the number of dimensions.
This paper is rather interesting about the limitations of the model -
http://www.econ2.jhu.edu/people/ccarroll/death.pdf
Posted by: Peter N | March 30, 2014 at 11:01 PM
Nick, you write:
"And that excess supply of money causes P and/or Y to increase until the quantity of money demanded adjusts to equal the quantity supplied. Say's Law, paradoxically, only applies to money itself. The supply of money creates its own demand."
This makes it sound like it takes some time for P and/or Y to increase. At least in terms of P, that seems consistent with the idea of sticky prices. So does that mean it's fair to re-write that final sentence to read:
"The supply of money eventually creates its own demand?"
Does that mean that at any one point in time, Say's Law is not necessarily true for money since P and/or Y may not yet have adjusted, and thus the quantity supplied does not yet match the quantity demanded? Is it helpful to introduce distinct concepts for the nominal demand for money (Mdn) vs the real demand for money (Mdr = Mdn/P) here? Thanks.
Posted by: Tom Brown | March 30, 2014 at 11:03 PM
Peter N, "So much for trying to keep it simple." Lol, ... sorry, you got my rapid endorsement for introducing the concept... followed by me actually thinking about it a bit. OK, so then it sounds like my 2nd hunch was correct: that by "feedback" in your denominator here:
"closedLoopGain = openLoopGain / (1 + feedback * openLoopGain)"
We could substitute Z^-1 (a unit delay block), true? Then there is a set of openLoopGains > 0 which would produce a stable system, with the steady state gain > openLoopGain over a range of openLoopGains with positive feedback (positive feedback meaning replace your "+" in the denominator with a "-").
Thanks for the link BTW, I'll take a look.
Posted by: Tom Brown | March 30, 2014 at 11:12 PM
Peter N, was that the correct paper? I searched for "Z-transform," "transform," "discrete time," "stability," "gain," "open loop," "closed loop"... and I didn't find those inside. Was there a particular section I should look at?
Posted by: Tom Brown | March 31, 2014 at 12:10 AM
Nick: I think the usual complaint is that many people assume multiplier must equals 1/reserve-requirement. In that case any increase in reserves results in a much larger increase in bank deposits. But as you say, an increase in CB money could be coincident with an increase in desired reserves.
Related to your previous posts on velocity - I want to thank you for enabling me to resolve a quandary I've had for years. When I travel, I recognize that I boost (very slightly) the economy of the locality I go to. I used to think of that as taking money from one place and spending it in another, but since deposits never really leave the jurisdiction of their CB (even Eurodollars have corresponding deposits in US banks), that didn't work. I realized yesterday that my spending increases the velocity of money in the locality I travel to. That should be sufficient to explain the small boost I provide.
Posted by: Squeeky Wheel | March 31, 2014 at 12:20 AM
Nick says “And commercial banks, neither individually nor collectively, can create loans, unless they can persuade people to hold their deposits and not hold central bank money instead.”
That’s true at full employment, but not necessarily true if the economy is below capacity. If commercial banks loaned money into existence when the economy was below capacity, and no one wanted to hold the resulting deposits, the extra money would be treated like a hot potato – people would try to spend it away – and the result would be increased demand.
Posted by: Ralph Musgrave | March 31, 2014 at 12:58 AM
Nick Rowe:
"desired reserves" is that level of reserves (or ratio of reserves to deposits) that commercial banks *choose* to keep"
So the money multiplier is the ratio of total deposits to total reserves, system wide?
Posted by: Min | March 31, 2014 at 01:14 AM
Nick, I am not exactly sure what the difference is between you and the "cultists" with regard to the money multiplier. Does it have to do with whether there actually is an iterative process of depositing and lending? On the one hand, the picture is that banks wait until they have deposits before deciding how much to lend, and on the other hand, banks do not base lending decisions on their deposits. Is that it?
If so, isn't that an empirical question, one that would not be difficult to answer?
Posted by: Min | March 31, 2014 at 01:31 AM
Min, there's another parameter; the "currency ratio" = c = (currency in circulation (not in bank vaults)) / (checkable deposits)
If the "reserve ratio" = r = (total reserves, i.e. vault cash + electronic) / (checkable deposits)
Then the money multiplier = (1+c)/(r+c) = M1/MB.
Since
M1 = (currency in circulation) + (checkable deposits)
MB = (currency in circulation) + (total reserves)
You can easily check and see the formula is true.
Posted by: Tom Brown | March 31, 2014 at 01:34 AM
Of course that may not be the "first year" money multiplier Nick is talking about in this post. That one may just be 1/r like you point out.
Posted by: Tom Brown | March 31, 2014 at 01:38 AM
"What matters is that those magnitudes are bigger than one."
What is so magical about one, in the sense that a multiplier of 1.1 would lead you to radically different conclusions than 0.9? If you want to explain the cycle with "shocks too small to see" don't you need a multiplier of 10, or 100?
This seems like a nit pick but it reminded me of another comment I heard on a podcast recently (Econtalk or LSE) talking about multiplier estimates either side of one (IIRC a range of 0.6-1.5, from Ramey) as a big problem when considering stimulus policy.
I couldn't understand why. 1 means extra government spending is completely "free" as far as crowding out the private sector goes (leaving aside the DWL of raising tax revenue), 0.6-1.5 means there might be a bit of crowding out or crowding in. But insofar as there is a minimum value for stimulus spending to be desirable, isn't 0 (+ a bit for the DWL of tax collection) rather than 1 the natural starting point?
Posted by: Declan | March 31, 2014 at 02:17 AM
Nick,
You may find this interesting and relevant to your post:
http://www.thomaspalley.com/docs/research/ad_and_debt.pdf
(HT Ramanan)
Posted by: JKH | March 31, 2014 at 04:47 AM
Tom Brown,
That was the right paper. I thought the math was more accessible than most such. A standard treatment would be
http://www.pitt.edu/~jduffy/courses/talk4.pdf
http://www.pitt.edu/~jduffy/courses/talk5.pdf
This is probably more than you want to know while still not being entirely clear, so I think, having gone through my bookmarks and downloads, that
http://www.econ.ku.dk/personal/henrikj/makok3_2012/Dynamics.pdf
and
http://ns.fujimori.cache.waseda.ac.jp/PKR/2013/asada.pdf
are probably more on point. The math is much clearer than Duffy.
Posted by: Peter N | March 31, 2014 at 05:22 AM
Nick, interesting post. You need to put all these post together and produce a monograph. It would be great for a money and banking class.
Posted by: David Beckworth | March 31, 2014 at 07:40 AM
Along these same lines, I also tried my hand at reconciling my views with endogenous money. Not sure how clear it is, but here it is: http://macromarketmusings.blogspot.com/2014/03/market-monetarism-and-endogenous-money.html
Posted by: David Beckworth | March 31, 2014 at 07:46 AM
Ralph: An excess supply of money will force up either Y and/or P. The slope of the Phillips Curve/AS curve determines which of those two will get forced up.
Declan: fair point. What matters is that those multipliers might be very big. Infinity is more of a magic number than one. But even when people think they can identify the original shock (e.g. the US housing market etc.) they often wonder why the recession was much bigger than the obvious direct effect, which suggests they are comparing it to one.
Thanks JKH. I had a quick read of it. I think he's too hung up on Steve Keen's assumption that V=1, which was just for simplicity.
Posted by: Nick Rowe | March 31, 2014 at 07:54 AM
David: thanks!
From reading your post, I think we are very much on the same page.
Posted by: Nick Rowe | March 31, 2014 at 09:12 AM
Mike Sproul says 'This defines "deposit" too narrowly. A commercial bank can issue 100 checking account dollars in exchange for nothing but a "deposit" of the borrower's $100 IOU, or a "deposit" of a $100 government bond (just like central banks do). '
They can do indeed do this but but when the 100 checking account dollars is used to buy something and the seller deposits the check in his bank account , won't the original bank need real reserves (not just the collateral) to settle ? It may have these reserves already, or need to get them after the initial loan, but at some point its going to need them, right ?
(Note: I think I can image a different banking system where banks could indeed issue money directly against collateral, and money would be truly endogenous - but that's just not how the current system works).
Posted by: The Market Fiscalist | March 31, 2014 at 09:30 AM
Peter N, Thanks for taking the time to dig those out. I haven't gone through all that yet, but the last two certainly used a lot more of the language I'm used to (I have yet to look at the 1st two).
Posted by: Tom Brown | March 31, 2014 at 09:37 AM
Clarification on "It may have these reserves already, or need to get them after the initial loan" from my earlier comment.....of course it will likely have available reserves already, but the new loan (when spent) may lead to it dropping below the optimal level of reserves and it may as a result need to take action to address that.
Posted by: The Market Fiscalist | March 31, 2014 at 09:55 AM
"And the medium of exchange is not like refrigerators, because we buy money in order to sell it again, not just to hold it. Suppliers of money, unlike suppliers of refrigerators, can "force" us to buy more money than we want to hold, because each buys it planning to sell it again to someone else. And that excess supply of money causes P and/or Y to increase until the quantity of money demanded adjusts to equal the quantity supplied."
Or alternatively, an excess supply of money causes money supply to be unprofitable, while P and Y remain constant. (Why would a bank issue money unprofitably? Wouldn't that be crazy? Yes, unless maybe the bank read in a textbook that an increase in the money supply would cause an increase in P or Y).
Posted by: Max | March 31, 2014 at 09:56 AM
The Market Fiscalist,
You are correct, in the case where the recipient of the funds banks at a different bank. And re: your second point: I've often imagined the same thing I think. I draw out the balance sheets here:
http://brown-blog-5.blogspot.com/2013/03/banking-example-12-loand-deposit.html
This one with a purchase:
http://brown-blog-5.blogspot.com/2013/03/banking-example-11.html
But in some sense, why did the CB need to temporarily create any liabilities at all there? I think that's what you're asking, right? Why couldn't Bank A go straight to owing Bank B the $100 in reserves and leave the CB out of it.
Posted by: Tom Brown | March 31, 2014 at 09:58 AM
The Market Fiscalist, you are correct. I draw out the balance sheets here: rather than a link, just Google
Banking Example #1.1
1st hit. I wondered the same thing: why can't Bank A just going straight to owing Bank B the reserves w/o the CB ever getting involved.
Posted by: Tom Brown | March 31, 2014 at 10:07 AM
Max: an individual bank will create more money when it is profitable for the individual bank to do so. That's not at issue. But what adjusts in response to that increased money creation?
Posted by: Nick Rowe | March 31, 2014 at 10:14 AM
Nick,
Saw your comment at Glasner's about how excess supply of money can still dominate shifts in the mix between base and bank money when the interest rate on bank money changes.
This may be a basic question that you've answer a thousand times before - but how do you relate excess supply or demand to velocity? Does excess supply or demand correlate with volatility of velocity?
Posted by: JKH | March 31, 2014 at 10:17 AM
Tom,
on "why can't Bank A just going straight to owing Bank B the reserves w/o the CB ever getting involved."
I can image a world where banks create their own currency unit (for example equal in value to a set bundle of goods). They then issue loans against collateral in this currency unit. If people deposit the money created by these loans in a different bank then they will need to transfer reserves just like in today's system but rather then being CB base money these reserves would consist of collateral equal in value to the reserves needed (there would need to be some efficient way of measuring the value of collateral in the chosen currency unit). Of course a bank that simply issues loans again collateral and then transfers the collateral would be a useless bank, so they would also need to make their money attractive to hold (that is attract customers willing to keep their balances with them). Making their money redeemable against the bundle of goods that defines the currency unit would be a good way of doing this.
In this system they probably should call the currency unit the "sproul".
Posted by: The Market Fiscalist | March 31, 2014 at 10:30 AM
JKH: good question. Rough answer (don't hold me precisely to this): excess supply of money = actual velocity is less than desired velocity. People want to spend money more quickly than they are actually spending it.
Posted by: Nick Rowe | March 31, 2014 at 11:06 AM
"... I think he's too hung up on Steve Keen's assumption that V=1, which was just for simplicity."
Yes there should be a multiplier of V(t)/2 on the ΔD terms. You might be able to calculate v(t) from Y(t) and D1(t) to get something like:
C1(t)= zY(t)- S(t)+ ((Y(t)/ D1(t)) / 2) * (ΔD1(t) + ΔD2(t))
I think his treatment of W is also a problem. Can you really hide the difference between his W and net worth in a2 (the propensity to consume from wealth). It's not a2(t) after all.
I expect a some of Keen's problems come from his requirement that the theory be stock-flow correct (by Godley standards). OTOH this makes it very easy to generate the necessary values to run simulations, which he has done.
Posted by: Peter N | March 31, 2014 at 11:25 AM
I think this paper on credit is worth a look. It looks at where consumer debt came from, and the extent to which future primary consumer surpluses can reduce debt. It may at least partly explain why the recovery has been so weak and protracted, and why the Fed has had to work so hard.
It's relevant to any discussion of the value of austerity. I learned a lot from it. The lead author is a regular here - J W Mason.
http://repec.umb.edu/RePEc/files/FisherDynamics.pdf
Posted by: Peter N | March 31, 2014 at 12:03 PM
Tom Brown: "Of course that may not be the "first year" money multiplier Nick is talking about in this post."
Thanks, Tom. For this and your previous note. :)
It helps to know what definition is being used. ;)
Posted by: Min | March 31, 2014 at 12:09 PM
Nick,
You asked "But what adjusts in response to that increased money creation?"
That may be 2 questions - what should normally adjust and what actually did.
It certainly didn't lead to an increase in the stock of broad money. A bit of a mystery and a bit scary -
Posted by: Peter N | March 31, 2014 at 12:16 PM
Peter N: "That may be 2 questions - what should normally adjust and what actually did."
Yep. What do we want to adjust, if the central bank is doing what we want it to do; and what actually adjusts if the central bank does what it actually does.
Posted by: Nick Rowe | March 31, 2014 at 12:32 PM
The failure of broad measures of money suppy to expand in the US (and the UK)following QE was predictable in a liquidity-trap recession. As far as I remember, Krugman did predict it on the basis of his analysis in his Japanese liquidity-trap paper. It was also predictable given US experience in the 1930s.
Posted by: Almar | March 31, 2014 at 03:00 PM
Palley on Keen:
http://monetaryrealism.com/thomas-palley-on-steve-keens-model-of-aggregate-demand/
Posted by: JKH | April 01, 2014 at 08:15 AM