« A simple story about non-reversibility of causation | Main | Earnings in the "Good Old Days" »

Comments

Feed You can follow this conversation by subscribing to the comment feed for this post.

Techincally, I think SW would argue that his model assumes no permanent helicopter drops, because it specifically assumes a passive fiscal policy that always maintains the same PV of total government liabilities. This pins down the price level, in a sort of but not exactly FTPL sense. Still, that is not the point you are making: Why doesn't even a FTPL-determined price level in his model rise as the liquidity premia on bonds/money declines in the liquidity trap? Why is it plausible that only inflation and not the price level is determined by the altering the convenience yield of liquid assets? This isn't a model of sticky prices, after all. Maybe an intuitive explanation is that the CB by assumption (idue to his about the passive fiscal authority maintaining the real value of government liabilities) is only temporarily affecting the liquidity premia (and will fully compensate with reversal in the future), such the price level is unaffected but the rental rate on money/bonds must still increase (inflation must decrease) during the period of the lower liquidity premia. This would make his model akin to asking what would happen if the CB outside of the liquidity trap started dropping helicopter money but promised to vacuum it all up and then some in (say) two years. Prices might remain unchanged but nominal interest rates could decline along with inflation. Instead of saying inflation declines because people demand a higher return on money given the lower convenience yield, you could say inflation declines because the expected future price level actually declines because the helicopter drops was a counterintuitively a sign of tighter monetary policy due to expected overcompensation from the future vacuum. This is kind of equivalent to a fixed, passive fiscal policy that automatically maintains the starting price level in his model (I think).

dlr: good try. You are making sense. But unfortunately, given the assumption you are making here: "Techincally, I think SW would argue that his model assumes no permanent helicopter drops, because it specifically assumes a passive fiscal policy that always maintains the same PV of total government liabilities. This pins down the price level, in a sort of but not exactly FTPL sense.", plus Steve's assumption here: "Since the liquidity payoffs on money and short-term government debt have gone down..." the only way both those assumptions can be satisfied at once is if the helicopter is immediately followed by a vacuum cleaner, which nullifies his thought-experiment before it has even started.

But for any helicopter drop there must exist a vacuum cleaner that slowly vacuums the money back up over time, at just the right speed that the helicopter drop causes no immediate change in the price level. But I don't think that's what he's saying. Or if it is, I don't think he realises he's saying it.

In other words: a higher level of the money supply causes a higher price level; a lower growth rate of the money supply causes a lower price level and a lower rate of inflation. So if you matched them up just right, you could have no change in the price level, but a lower rate of inflation.

But if that's what he is saying, why doesn't he just say it? Like I did, just then. This is a very old result. Cagan 1968, I think, where the inflation rate temporarily overshoots the growth rate in the money supply when that growth rate suddenly increases. So if you have an increased level of the money supply, and a lower growth rate from then on, and you got the numbers just right, there would be a fall in the inflation rate with no jump up or down in the price level.

Nick,

I just wrote up a blog post criticizing Steve's view. I think the problem is that he misinterprets causality. Sure, in equilibrium the marginal value of your cash holdings should equal the inflation rate, but this could arise either from the inflation rate falling or people drawing down cash holdings, thereby increasing the marginal value of liquidity.

Yichuan: good post. I left a comment.

I don't think you need the vacuum cleaner to match up just right in terms of timing. What you need is expectations of a lower future price level to just offset the lower convenience yield. We could imagine a CB with this kind of strange reaction function, and it is maybe less strained than imagining the perfectly timed vacuum, but it is still strained. This is what I think of as the passive reaction function of the fiscal authority in the SW model. The real value of government debt at all times remains the same. If the government helicopters money, it must make an implicit promise to sop up that money in the future. To the extent the helicoptered money sits around for a while and lowers the convenience yield, it must promise to sop up the money and then some (otherwise the debt has lost value), such that real value of government liabilities never changes, whereas the inflation rate can vary. I think it is this presumed, offsetting policy reaction function that is the key to funny results from the model as opposed to instability or magical equilibrium hopping.

Nick, I don't think Williamson's post is about helicopter money. It's about QE, i.e. central bank purchases of already existing bonds. Your helicopter money involves handing new money out for free, which is not the same thing.

Nick,

Seems to me the fundamental communication problem stems from the fact that the model admits multiple equilibria.

Both stories are consistent with equilibrium. In your story the higher price level lowers the real stock of money back to what it was before, so as before people are happy holding it.

In SW's story inflation immaculately falls, raising the real return to money and making people happy to hold a higher real stock of it. That also works in the sense of being consistent with equilibrium in the model.

To settle the argument you need to go, as Krugman did, to other markets, in particular the ones where inflation actually happens. It's there that you're story will be consistent with behaviour and SW's will not. You started to do this in this post but omitted the details, you need to fill them in (explain why excess money stocks translate into increased demand for goods and why that means higher prices).

You can only win by going outside financial markets though, within SW's context both stories, and convex combinations of the two, will work and you don't ever quite win.

Non-economist trying to follow along here, but SW has lost me. Has he explained anywhere how he gets inflation to fall?

Patrick, will a simple "no" suffice?

This thread of thread, which began with Kocherlakota's fault, is frustrating. If a renowned economist like Stephen Williamson shows an understanding of monetary issues that falls far short of the understanding of a layman - where has macroeconomics gone?

Is "linearized around some steady state" DSGE analysis of cashless economies the end of macroeconomics? Or perhaps the beginning of a fresh start?

Williamson: "in order to induce asset-holders to hold the money and the short-term government debt, the rates of return on money and short-term government debt must go up."

IOW, **unless** the rates of return on money and short-term gov't debt go up, asset-holders will **not** hold money and short-term gov't debt, i. e., they will spend.

Nick Rowe: "People do not wish to hold more money. . . . So people will try to spend their excess supply of money. This creates an excess demand for goods. . . ."

Isn't Williamson actually conceding your point? :)

@ Philippe

Williamson is not talking about QE, because the Treasury is increasing the deficit. QE is the Fed's doing. But I agree, simply increasing the deficit is not helicopter money, because of distribution. Like the rain, helicopter money falls on the just and the unjust. :)

Adam P: "Seems to me the fundamental communication problem stems from the fact that the model admits multiple equilibria."

Sure. But so does every simple model with money, unless you start talking about what happens when P goes to zero or infinity. The literature on this started in the 1970's.

Assume real money supply = real money demand:

M/P = L(Y,i) where i = r + Pdot/P and where dL/di < 0

Assume M, Y, and r are all fixed exogenously and never change.

There is one solution where Pdot/P =0. That's the standard solution. But there is an infinity of other solutions where P and Pdot/P are both higher (or both lower) than the standard solution, and M/P solwly falls to 0 (or rises to infinity). And we normally rule out those non-standard solutions by saying we could always use the money as TP, or something (or a $1 note could buy the world).

Wish I could remember the name of the economist who did a paper on all this stuff in the 1970's.

Herbert: "... where has macroeconomics gone?"

That's what I've been asking myself.

As far as the Thread of threads that started with Kocherlakota is concerned, this post is GAME OVER. When he says it in words, not math, it's just too totally obvious to see what the problem is. All that's left is the post-mortem, to see why the teaching of basic macro/money died. And epidemiology, to see how far the rot has spread into the grad skools. Then we start again, with the basics of the quantity theory. And drag a load of old guys out of retirement, so we can explain really basic stuff like: "the central bank sets M, but people set M/P given their expectations of future M, and P adjusts so that Md=Ms".

Reading some of the comments on Steve's post, it's obvious that some guys (probably fancypants grad students) STILL don't get it, even though he has (unwittingly) laid out the problem as clearly as he could.

And I took a quick skim of the blogosphere this morning. AFAIK, there is me, Bob Murphy, and Yichuan Wang, who have noticed the problem. God help us all.

I can't tell whether Steve now gets it, from his reply to my comment on his blog (where I said what I said here). He talks about "real bonds", which is OK for bonds, because you can assume all bonds are indexed. But you can't index money. It's the medium of account. You can't index a thing to itself.

Time to round up all the Minnesota etc grads, and put them back in basic training. I wonder how many generations there are?

dlr: "I don't think you need the vacuum cleaner to match up just right in terms of timing."

In continuous time, you do.

All in logs: M(t) = P(t) - b.Pdot(t).

Ruling out the explosive/implosive solutions, that means:

M(t) = P(t) - b.Mdot(t)

To ensure P(t) does not jump when M(t) jumps up, you need Mdot(t) to jump down at the same time.

Steve is talking about helicopter bonds. But it makes no difference. The government sets B+M. If B and M are perfect substitutes (it makes a little difference if they are imperfect substitutes) people have a demand for (B+M)/P (or B+(M/P) if the bonds are indexed). If helicopters increase B+M, P increases to restore the original (B+M)/P.

Or, simply change Steve's thought-experiment to helicopter money, because his reasoning ought to work exactly the same way.

Nick,

The 2nd paragraph of your post needs a slight adjustment. You assume that heli-drops automatically and immediately cause inflation. They won’t if the economy is nowhere near capacity, or put another way, if unemployment is above NAIRU.

I.e. (as MMTers are constantly pointing out) if unemployment is above NAIRU, the INITIAL effect of a decent sized heli-drop is primarily to increase output. But when unemployment reaches NAIRU, the effect is primarily to exacerbate inflation.

Ralph: Steve is assuming perfectly flexible prices and market-clearing. Therefore, so am I. That's not the issue. It's irrelevant. So are MMTers. This is Old Monetarists (plus everyone else who understands basic macro/money) vs so-called New Monetarists.

Ralph,

"the INITIAL effect of a decent sized heli-drop is primarily to increase output"

You say "primarily", which indicates there will actually be a mix of both increased output and higher prices, not just increased output.

Philippe and Ralph: stop talking about irrelevant details. Only the Big Story matters.

Ralph: "Re Steve and you assuming “perfectly flexible prices” that is a 110% unrealistic."

Of course it's 110% unrealistic. And it's 120% off-topic. And you are 130% pissing me off by ignoring my previous request. So I unpublished you.

The following 2 statement both sound like they could be true

1) An increase in the money supply will drive deflation since people will need a bigger return to hold the increased money
2) An increase in the money supply will drive inflation since people will spend some of the new money.

It is easy to see the market mechanism that drives 2, but warder to see what drives 2).

If prices were set centrally (and supply then allowed to adjust to meet these prices) then the authorities could engineer 1) by reducing prices over time so that people would be happy to hold the increased money because they liked the extra returns they got.

It also seems possible that if we lived in a world where prices never went up but did go down (perhaps productivity growth is very high) that people might reduce spending after an increase in the money supply in anticipation of increased deflation and drive result 1) via an expectations mechanism.

So while intuitively seems like 2) normally holds it is possible to build consistent (if somewhat contrived) models where 1) would hold.


And one can imagine a model where the extra money is created by buying up another good that is negatively correlated to the price level.

Lets say QE is done by buying up (and closing down) stores. Assume that at a given money supply the amount of trade (and the price level) is a function of the number of stores.

In this world an increased money supply may well drive the results that Williamson claims.

Doesn't the Fiscal authority pin down the price in SW's model?

"So people will try to spend their excess supply of money" and the government will raise taxes just enough to absorb the excess supply of money.

c2114661: If Steve had said "If the central bank announces it will reduce the growth rate in the money supply (whether or not it does a once-and-for-all increase in the level of the money supply at the same time it makes the announcement), the result will be to reduce the inflation rate." all economists would reply "Sure, a declining money supply causes deflation, so what else is new?".

[tears hair out] The whole idea that printing money reduces inflation...

Nick, I don't know how you and Sumner stay sane. I guess I'm lucky to work in a profession (programming) where when you're wrong, you find out immediately and don't spend all your time discussing models that are clearly wrong.

I thought the claim was that the equilibrium didn't have a story behind it. Is that not correct? I agree it seems like a bizarre setup, but there is no issue with causality here.

Nick: "Wish I could remember the name of the economist who did a paper on all this stuff in the 1970's."

Maybe Brock, A simple perfect foresight monetary model (1975)?

Nick,your last few posts and Yichuan's one linked to above have been great on this topic. Regarding your point on getting back to basic monetary economics, what is needed a good undergraduate monetary economics textbook that does this to train the next generation. The current monetary economic textbooks really fall short here.

Interesting Twitter exchange between Noah Smith & Tony Yates:

NS: The "QE/deflation" debate is interesting because Williamson's model says stimulus works, and Krugman is saying it's not microfounded enough.

TY: i thought he was saying its not verbalfounded enough. and williamson said so what.

NS: No, I think Krugman/DeLong were saying, show us explicitly how the firm sector works. Which is a legit request, since Lagos-Wright does show it, but Williamson doesn't.

TallDave: "Nick, I don't know how you and Sumner stay sane."

I don't. Dunno about Scott.

c211. Dunno. At first I thought it was stability. But with Steve's latest post, it's more than that. He totally misses the standard comparative statics, which does have a stability story behind it.

Kevin: "Maybe Brock, A simple perfect foresight monetary model (1975)?"

BINGO!

Gotta go.

If the Fed succeeded in buying up everything, then there would be deflation (or else the Fed would be paying interest).

This is an amusing point, but it doesn't tell you what would happen if the Fed tried to buy everything (and not with the goal of causing deflation).

Expert A and Expert B are having a debate. A claims that B is making elementary mistakes. Two things are probably true (i) B is not being clear, and (ii) A misunderstands what B is saying.

As Phillippe and dlr said above, the price level in Steve's model is determined by the PV of consolidated government debt. Steve doesn't focus on the price level, perhaps because he doesn't find it interesting. In his model, a helicopter drop would raise the price level but decrease future inflation. This is what Nick called overshooting above. Steve tried to say this by reference to finance, e.g., when the risk premium on a stock goes down, the current price jumps up and expected future returns are lower. His critics have focused on the "price jumps up part" because that is what they are interested in, whereas he has focused on the "future returns are lower part" because that is what he is interested in.

Max: just take the limit of what I have said above. If people knew the Bank of Canada was trying to buy everything, nobody would sell, at any finite price level. Money would become worthless.

Aaron: maybe. But if Steve really understood all that, he would predict a jump up or down in the price level whenever the US government goes into or out of one of its...debt-limit shutdowns (I've forgotten the name)....which didn't happen.

Nick,

I still have a vague feeling that something's not quite right. Maybe we are being too cocky here.

My uneasiness is coming from the fact that Williamson wasn't on Larry Kudlow's show, and threw out the verbal logic "hey the return to money needs to rise, so inflation rate falls."

Instead, Williamson derived his result inside a formal model with an equilibrium result. So, are we really right for saying he ignored something obvious? I.e., does he NOT have a utility function for real cash balances in his model?

Market Fiscalist: "The following 2 statement both sound like they could be true

"1) An increase in the money supply will drive deflation since people will need a bigger return to hold the increased money
"2) An increase in the money supply will drive inflation since people will spend some of the new money."

Doesn't 1) require that people hold the increased money instead of spending it? And doesn't that require that they are getting a bigger return to do so? IOW, doesn't it beg the question, assuming the conclusion?

Bob: Steve says: "Since the liquidity payoffs on money and short-term government debt have gone down, in order to induce asset-holders to hold the money and the short-term government debt, the rates of return on money and short-term government debt must go up."

It does not matter, for this point, if the declining marginal liquidity payoffs are derived from some underlying model of costly exchange, or just bunging money in the utility function. Taking that declining marginal liquidity payoff as given, there are two ways to restore equilibrium: a rise in the price level; a fall in the inflation rate. Steve doesn't see the first. The first has a story behind it. The second explains why Zimbabwe had accelerating hyperdeflation.

Look at Steve's response to my comment on his blog.

Min: yes, increased money holding and increased returns would take place simultaneous. I think it is probably possible to invent models that explain how this could happen.

I assume (without having read it) that SWs paper outlines a model where this does happen, and that he is claiming that this models mirrors what is actually happening the real economy.

I am therefore not sure that describing the HPE and/or simply asserting that when the price level increases people will want to hold more of it is a good way of dealing with his arguments.

Never reason from the price change. Williamson's critics reason from the price change (change in liquidity premium), they assume QE changes prices through AD only. Williamson argues AD days are long gone, and QE today is a supply side measure, raising output while lowering prices. Read his latest post.

Market Fiscalist: "yes, increased money holding and increased returns would take place simultaneous. I think it is probably possible to invent models that explain how this could happen."

But Williamson is not just claiming that it is possible, he says that it *must* happen in a liquidity trap. The burden of proof is on him, and the structure of his argument is that of begging the question.

Vaidas: I am not reasoning from a price change. I am following Steve, and assuming that the marginal benefits of liquidity are a decreasing function of the (real) stock of liquid assets. So when the stock of liquid assets increases, the marginal benefits of holding liquid assets now falls below equilibrium level. Just like if the Treasury increased the stock of cars, the marginal benefits of their transportation services now falls below the equilibrium level. therefore the price of liquid assets (or cars) will fall. But money, unlike cars, is the medium of account. So a fall in the price of money means a rise in the price of goods. And for money, unlike cars, the marginal benefits of ownership depends on M/P, because we don't care about how many bits of paper are in our pockets, only about the real value of those bits of paper.

Beckworth's post showing that SW claims do not hold up empirically was brought up over at SW blog. Beckworth was directly responded to SW's claims that inflation has been declining over past three years because of QE. When confronted with the evidence, SW hides behind "not serious empirical work." How convenient. http://newmonetarism.blogspot.com/2013/12/the-intuition-is-in-financial-markets.html?showComment=1386172834195#c5653288304647455928

I think that there's a way that Williamson can be technically right: the opportunity cost of holding money is somewhere between negative and zero, so your premise of "people do not wish to hold more money" is currently false.

At the moment, the Federal Reserve pays one quarter basis point interest on excess reserves. Meanwhile, the treasury rates are one half of that, going out to a year.

So while the Fed can helicopter all the money it wants via QE, banks can earn a risk-free profit by selling short-term treasuries to hold excess reserves. That explains recent behaviour: money held in excess reserves is not circulating, and as such it doesn't affect the price level. If the fed raises the funds rate but keeps its low interest rate on excess reserves, then those reserves will be more profitably spent on treasuries and other debt instruments (and ultimately real investment) instead.

Graph: The M2 money velocity (red, right scale) has collapsed since the beginning of QE, commensurate with the increase in excess reserves (blue, left log scale). However, subtracting the excess reserves from M2 stock gives a much more stable "effective M2 velocity," comparable to mid-2000s levels.

A commenter at Stephen Williamson's blog named "Anonymous" pointed out that there is empirical evidence that QE increases inflation, namely, he referred to David Beckworth's post ("Taking the Model to the Data") which also mentions my econometric results.

(By the way, has anyone noticed the large number of commenters named "Anonymous" at Williamson's blog? I know there's more than one because they have to keep identifying themself by when they last commented, or what their previous point was. What on earth is that all about?!?)

Here is Stephen Williamson's response:

"In order to properly confront the data, we need a model of how QE works, and then we have to argue that the data is somehow consistent with that. I don't think we would call that serious empirical work in that sense."

http://newmonetarism.blogspot.com/2013/12/the-intuition-is-in-financial-markets.html?showComment=1386177831449#c7314592028317641767

Of course the implication is that David doesn't have a model of how QE works (and evidently nor do I). Now, this is of course completely untrue. In fact in that very post, David discusses, and links to, the paper he cowrote with Joshua Hendrickson ("The Supply of Transaction Assets, Nominal Income, and Monetary Policy Transmission") in which he extends the very same monetary search framework of Lagos-Wright that Williamson uses in order to show the effects of QE.

But more importantly, the main subject of David's post isn't his own model, but Williamson's model, which as David demonstrates (and as I further demonstrate in comments) is inconsistent with the empirical evidence. So rather than a dearth of economic models, we have a surplus, and the model which is the subject of David's post seems to be failing the test.

At this point, it's taking every ounce of energy I can muster to keep being as civil as possible. But frankly Williamson keeps making factual, empirical and theoretical claims which range from being demonstrably false to being utterly ridiculous. Aren't there any real world repurcussions for this kind of behavior?

macroman: Yep. But somehow I find the empirical evidence of Zimbabwe's lack of hyperdeflation more compelling.

Majromax: "I think that there's a way that Williamson can be technically right: the opportunity cost of holding money is somewhere between negative and zero, so your premise of "people do not wish to hold more money" is currently false."

But that was Steve's premise as well. They do not wish to hold more money at the existing price level and inflation rate.

Mark: I'm think all those Anonymous commenters are probably PhD students EJMR types. I could be wrong.

Actually, I'm pretty sure Steve now realises there's a problem here. His latest post (though it's maybe actually quite interesting, I think) is a smokescreen. It will take a bit for some of his followers to cotton on.

There's something going on here, but it's nothing fancy. PK asked for a story; SW gave one missing the key plot twist. Why doesn't SW see this? Look, PK (etc.) thinks with models, SW (etc.) thinks *about* them. SW says: anything worthy of the name "thought" should take the form of a model, the rest is small talk. But imagine someone saying: anything worthy of the name "navigation" should take the form of a map. What do you say to such a person? Maybe nothing, you drop them somewhere with a map and let them find their way home. But what's the equivalent to that in this case? No wonder Nick despaired of getting SW to see there's a problem, and no wonder SW struggles so mightily to see it. That SW can achieve the reputation of a "top-flight" macroeconomist is no surprise -- you see this sort of thing in every field, not least those in which rigorously specified models are set against highly complicated phenomena.

PS - I left a comment to the same effect on SW's blog. He immediately deleted it. This is no surprise, if I'm right: he was bound to find it thoughtless...

PPS - Sorry, couldn't resist.

Did you see Williamson's latest?

newmonetarism.blogspot.ca/2013/12/intuition-part-ii.html

jonah: Dunno. I gotta give Steve credit for writing that Intuition post. It was very clear, and I was following fine up till the bit I quoted above. And then it was also very clear to me just where his reasoning went wrong.

Keshav: yes. I skimmed it. It's not really addressing the problem I'm talking about here. But I have a hunch it might be an interesting post in it's own right, even if it's not quite right. Liquidity does matter, for trade. And recessions are declines in trade.

Nick,
I think you haven't read Steve's latest post yet.
You are still reasoning from the price change, you focus on prices while ignoring NGDP. When the stock of liquid assets increases, NGDP grows - this is the uncontroversial part. Only the following is controversial - how much do real rates change when NGDP goes up? Steve says real rates rise so much that in the new equilibrium with higher stock of liquid assets the marginal benefit of liquidity goes up, not down.
Regarding empirical issues, I am not ready to agree with Steve yet. I am a card carrying market monetarist and the main benefit of QE today is higher AD. However, Steve is right in reminding that there are AS benefits too.

Min: Good point. Here some more thoughts:

Assume 2 reasons to hold money at a given point in time
1) to spend it at some point ion the future
2) to get a return on it

If people end up with more money than they previously had and the return on it has not changed then they will spend it.

But if you think that the liquidity trap means that increasing the money supply won't increase spending then this can't happen. It would be logical to assume that its the return on money that must do the adjusting (via deflation). This would be true whether or not you have a good explanation for the mechanics of what drives the deflation .

I assume that the increase in money is via asset swaps rather than helicopter drops.

Nick:

"M(t) = P(t) - b.Mdot(t)

To ensure P(t) does not jump when M(t) jumps up, you need Mdot(t) to jump down at the same time."

I apologize because I'm sure I'm just missing something obvious here, but can you help me understand this in words? Take a simple case where a CB starts dropping money out of helicopters but simultaneously announces a lower future price level target (relative to its previous target). Why can't the future price level target plus the required real return on money pin down the current price level irrespective of when they actually sop up the money or allow the convenience yield to increase? If it is later they may have to do more of it (the reverse of promising to be irresponsible) or have a lower price level target to get a result where the price level doesn't immediately jump and also lower inflation -- but I don't understand why the precise timing is needed to eliminate the explosive/implosive equilibria.

Vaidas: " However, Steve is right in reminding that there are AS benefits too."

I only skimmed Steve's second post. But I did catch that bit, and I think it's interesting. An increase in M shifts both the AS and AD curves right. But it would have to shift the AS right by more than the AD, if it were going to cause a fall in the price level, which is empirically dubious, (and I'm not sure about stability, because I haven't thought about it yet).

Gotta go teach.

Mark -- Yeoman work as usual. Civility is often hard but you rarely regret it later. (And let me again give thanks for the fact that in my profession I can hit "Execute" and end all argument with the result.)

Nick, yes, it is empirically dubious - even in Japan we see Abenomics helping with sticky prices and wages. But I see no theoretical problems. If you assume, as Steve does, that problems with sticky prices are insignificant, and that there are big problems with financial intermediation, Steve's result is exactly what you will get. By the way, in Steve's case, central bank is a bank.

The good news is that Steve's model is one more argument for NGDPLT, and against IT. IT may be not very stable when central bank makes mistakes with QE.

Majromax,

"However, subtracting the excess reserves from M2 stock gives a much more stable "effective M2 velocity," comparable to mid-2000s levels."

Are excess reserves in M2 in the first place?

The big distortion in M2 seems to me to be financial business holding more deposits after the collapse of the interbank lending market and the shadow banking system-

http://research.stlouisfed.org/fred2/graph/fredgraph.png?&id=M2SL_LTDACBM027SBOG_GDP_FBTCDTQ027S&scale=Left&range=Custom&cosd=1974-01-01&coed=2013-10-01&line_color=%230000ff&link_values=false&line_style=Solid&mark_type=NONE&mw=4&lw=1&ost=-99999&oet=99999&mma=0&fml=c%2Fd&fq=Quarterly&fam=avg&fgst=lin&transformation=lin_lin_lin_lin&vintage_date=2013-12-04_2013-12-04_2013-12-04_2013-12-04&revision_date=2013-12-04_2013-12-04_2013-12-04_2013-12-04

- whereas the household and business money demand has been on the same gradual downward trend it's had for the 21rst century and doesn't suggest any sort of infinite liquidy preference-

http://research.stlouisfed.org/fred2/graph/fredgraph.png?&id=M2SL_LTDACBM027SBOG_GDP_FBTCDTQ027S_DABSHNO_TSDABSNNCB_MMFSABSNNCB_NCBCDCA_NNBCDCA_TSDABSNNB&scale=Left&range=Custom&cosd=1974-01-01&coed=2013-10-01&line_color=%230000ff&link_values=false&line_style=Solid&mark_type=NONE&mw=4&lw=1&ost=-99999&oet=99999&mma=0&fml=c%2F%28e%2Bg%2Bh%2Bf%2Bi%2Bj%29&fq=Quarterly&fam=avg&fgst=lin&transformation=lin_lin_lin_lin_lin_lin_lin_lin_lin_lin&vintage_date=2013-12-04_2013-12-04_2013-12-04_2013-12-04_2013-12-04_2013-12-04_2013-12-04_2013-12-04_2013-12-04_2013-12-04&revision_date=2013-12-04_2013-12-04_2013-12-04_2013-12-04_2013-12-04_2013-12-04_2013-12-04_2013-12-04_2013-12-04_2013-12-04

Am I missing something about Williamson's latest post (Intuition Part II)? I thought his model had flexible wages/prices; how can there then be a shortage of liquid assets?

I mean, I suppose I can see it if a lot of your liquid assets are also real goods in their own right (e.g. cows as money), but I don't think that's the case in his model.

Market Fiscalist: "If people end up with more money than they previously had and the return on it has not changed then they will spend it.

"But if you think that the liquidity trap means that increasing the money supply won't increase spending then this can't happen. It would be logical to assume that its the return on money that must do the adjusting (via deflation). This would be true whether or not you have a good explanation for the mechanics of what drives the deflation ."

As for helicopter drops, some of that money gets into the hands of poor people and unemployed people who have little choice but to spend it. Even better, if we want money to be spent, is to target people who will spend it, eh?

Another commenter named "Anonymous" said the following in Stephen Williamson's latest post:

"David Beckworth empirical results reject your hypothesis."

And Stephen Williamson responded:

"That's not serious empirical work."

http://newmonetarism.blogspot.com/2013/12/intuition-part-ii.html?showComment=1386187907396#c5531693717983569198

Recall that so far the only empirical evidence that Stephen Williamson has offered in support of his model is a graph of year on year PCEPI inflation which he claims shows inflation has been falling for three years (actually, it's more like two).

In contrast David estimates a two variable VAR with 6 and 12 lags in which the impulse response of core PCEPI to the Fed's Treasury holdings is the opposite of what is consistent with Williamson's model.

In addition, in comments I describe my own VAR Granger causality test results, and my own 4-variable VAR estimates which are contrary to the predictions of Williamson's model. And by my count so far we have found three (maybe four) research papers with VAR estimates contrary to the predictions of Williamson's model.

I wonder what qualifies as "serious empirical work" in Williamson's estimation?

Hey Nick. Do you agree with Murphy when he says this?

" what Williamson’s argument leaves out is the fact that, other things equal, you want to hold more money when its purchasing power falls. This is because people want to hold a certain amount of real cash balances. Just focusing on this effect, you would think that as price inflation occurs, people want to hold more money. So this effect works in the opposite direction from the effect that Williamson isolates."

I thought it's about the HPE that makes people want to get rid of the extra dollars?

dlr: on thinking about it, you may be right.

Mike Sax: the quantity of money demanded is a positive function (proportional to) the price level, and a negative function of the expected rate of inflation. That is very standard economics. That is what Bob Murphy is saying, but he wasn't very careful saying it.

Alex: even with flexible prices and wages, things like interest rates and inflation rates can affect the real stock of money people hold in equilibrium. I would need to read Steve's second post carefully to work out if what he's saying makes sense.

Nick,

Here's how I read Williamson. When he says "rate of return" I read "natural rate of interest" and when he says "inflation" I read "equilibrium rate of inflation".

So all he is saying here is:

1) If the treasury issues more debt the natural rate (equilibrium risk-free real rate of return) must increase. Check.

2) Since nominal rates are at zero (liquidity trap) and the natural rate has increased, the (equilibrium) rate of inflation must be lower. Check.

3) Therefore in a liquidity trap more government debt lowers the (equilibrium) inflation rate. Check.

All of which is totally conventional equilibrium reasoning. Pretty well the only thing that is going on here is the same old sleight of hand by which equilibrium inflation becomes expected inflation.

But then in his attempt to justify the equilibrium assumption he says that he thinks "it's fair to argue that any of those short run effects have played themselves out in the financial crisis and its aftermath, and now we're looking at the effects I've described." The problem, of course, is that the thought experiment he actually described is a new issuance of debt right now, five years after the start of the liquidity trap. The non-neutralities that have to play out are the ones that occur *as a result* of the debt issuance, and we have good reason to suspect that those will be inflationary. Whether or not the non-neutralities that occurred as a result of the financial crisis have already played themselves out is irrelevant. (In reality, non-neutralities don't "play themselves out." Rather they spiral out of control if left to themselves, and have to be fixed by active policy).

Nick:
"An increase in M shifts both the AS and AD curves right. But it would have to shift the AS right by more than the AD, if it were going to cause a fall in the price level, which is empirically dubious, (and I'm not sure about stability, because I haven't thought about it yet)."

I've been thinking about this and in my opinion Williamson's model doesn't really translate very well into AD-AS Model terms. QE causes an increase in the level of transactions and hence in the level of real consumption. But it also causes a decline in the rate of inflation without causing a shift in the price level.

In level terms the price level is fixed in any period and all the central bank can do is choose the level of real consumption. In dynamic terms, real consumption doesn't change except in jumps, so the only thing the central bank can choose is the rate of inflation. So in the first case you have a horizontal line and in the second case you have a vertical line. Make of it what you will.

If this interpretation is correct it also raises another empirical problem for Williamson's model. Where is the sudden increase in real consumption due to QE?

Ryan Avent's latest is worth a look; two noteworthy points:

"Prolonged QE is effectively a signal that the central bank is unwilling commit to higher inflation."

"What matters is not what QE does, but what QE means. So is QE deflationary? Sure, sometimes. But that's not really QE's fault."

Karsten: that interpretation is fine with me. Start in equilibrium. Have the central bank credibly announce a lower inflation target, with no jump in the equilibrium price level, and what happens? The inflation rate drops, nominal interest rates drop, the central bank needs to do an OMO purchase of bonds because the demand for money has increased. Standard macro.

Mark: suppose I took a standard model, and added the assumption that a low level of M/P will reduce Y, because money really is needed as a medium of exchange. The long run phillips curve would now slope the "wrong" way. High inflation means low M/P which means low Y and high U. That's a perfectly reasonable model. High inflation has real costs.

Kevin: yes, I liked Ryan Avent's post. He's on the same page as my previous post, on *why* did the central bank increase nominal interest rates?

Nick, good points. I really liked the set-up of Steve's post, up until his "To get to the point" paragraph.

He brings up a scenario in which we are at the zero-lower bound but cash exhibits a liquidity premium. I don't understand how this can be. If cash exhibits a liquidity premium, that means that cash owners enjoy a marginally valued flow of liquidity services. They will only rent this cash out at some positive rate high enough to compensate them for forgoing those services. In which case, we're not at the zero lower bound. In short, it's impossible to be at the ZLB and for cash to exhibit a liquidity premium -- the moment the latter occurs, we must be off of the ZLB. Am I missing anything?

JP: I think you misread him. Steve says: "Thus, in the liquidity trap we are in, the liquidity premia on money and short-term government debt are the same, and positive."

At the ZLB, money has no liquidity premium over bonds, but both money and bonds have a liquidity premium over other less liquid assets. Which makes sense to me.

If money & bonds have a liquidity premium over less liquid assets at the zero lower bound, that would imply that the overnight lending rate is higher than 0. After all, trades in the overnight market represent a 24 exchange of money for illiquid claims to money. Can we have a positive overnight rate yet be at the ZLB?

JP: Dunno. That's still pretty liquid compared to houses, cars, machine tools, and human capital.

Ok, but that still doesn't explain to me how we can have a positive overnight rate and still be at the ZLB. If any sort of liquidity premium on central bank money exists, then the overnight rate must be >0 and we're off the ZLB. How do we ever reach Steve's initial setup such that a liquidity premium on money exists at the ZLB? Do you get my confusion or am I so confused that I'm confusing you?

JP Koning:

"If any sort of liquidity premium on central bank money exists, then the overnight rate must be >0"

I don't think this is true. Money has a liquidity advantage over overnight deposits, but if there's enough money around, the marginal value of this advantage goes to zero. Money and overnight deposits collectively have (putatively) a liquidity advantage over long-term bonds, but the amount of money that it takes to make the marginal value of the money-vs-overnight-deposits liquidity advantage go to zero is not necessarily enough to also make the marginal value of the money-and-overnight-deposits-vs-long-term-bonds liquidity advantage go to zero. Being at the zero bound implies that the former has gone to zero, but this does not imply that the latter has also gone to zero. In Steve's setup, there is enough money around to satiate the market with the type of liquidity that is specific to money in comparison with overnight deposits, but not enough to satiate the market with the type of liquidity that is shared by both money and overnight deposits in comparison with long-term bonds.

Nick (and Vaidas)

"An increase in M shifts both the AS and AD curves right. But it would have to shift the AS right by more than the AD, if it were going to cause a fall in the price level"

But there are no nominal rigidities in this model, are there? So if one-time shifts in AS and AD were to affect the price level, they would do so immediately. And as I understand it there is no jump in the price level, up or down, so the AS and AD shifts must exactly balance. Maybe there is some feature of the model that assures this will be the case. In other words, to compensate for the reduced liquidity premium, people bid up the price level immediately so that it will subsequently decline over time, but the supply-side effect of the increased liquidity causes a permanent reduction in the price level that exactly offsets the immediate demand-side effect. So you end up with a price level that doesn't jump but that subsequently goes on a downward trajectory. I can't offhand imagine what feature could force the AS and AD effects to exactly offset each other, but if there is such a feature, I will reserve judgment on its plausibility until I understand it better. (I must say, Steve's blog post doesn't give me much confidence as to what that feature might be or even that he can explain the supply-side effect at all, but maybe he's just not expressing himself well, or maybe I've misunderstood.)

Did your spam filter eat my other comment, responding to JP Koning?

Andy, if the spam filter doesn't resurrect it, I'm hoping you remember what you wrote as I'm quite curious what you have to say.

The chart on the macroecoonmics wiki shows the money supply (helidrops) and inflation are closely correlated. Didn't know so much of the 19th cenutry was deflationary...
Figured out my critique of macro. Since the GD at least, avoiding sharp price movements has been considered good. I'd guess at underlying is that the marginal ease to get oil vs the utility of oil have been pretty stable. Gold and oil and wheat have moved in tandem pretty regularly over the decades and longer (wheat and gold since the Bible).
In the future, the underlying human capital and technologies will be sharper; either very good or very bad. So we'd want sharp price increases. Cheaper healthcare if we get regenerative medicine, more expensive if we get pandemics. It isn't just based on a stable price of oil inputs anymore.

The comments to this entry are closed.

Search this site

  • Google

    WWW
    worthwhile.typepad.com
Blog powered by Typepad