« Fiscal Equity, Taxes and GTHA Transit | Main | On the percentage of Canada covered by water (totally off topic) »

Comments

Feed You can follow this conversation by subscribing to the comment feed for this post.

It seems to me it comes down to what you can show. For instance a country with an AS curve. That AS curve does not change if its trade is balanced. However, if that country runs a trade deficit, its AS curve shifts to the right, (and if it runs a trade surplus its AS curve shifts to the left,) and the equilibrium point moves down (or up,) the downward sloping AD curve, changing the price level faced by domestic firms. However, domestic firms produce on the original AS curve, so their revenue is reduced. And since their demand is equal to their revenue, assuming no borrowing, the AD curve shifts downward. If we assume we are in a region where the AS curve is no longer vertical, but upward sloping, then the quantity produced by domestic firms also decreases, and we enter a contractionary, and deflationary, spiral. (Similarly, a country running a trade surplus enters an expansionary and inflationary spiral.)

I haven't been too precise with the definitions of AS and AD, except to keep them constant. Any validity to this argument?

greg: we put domestic production (GDP) on the horizontal axis. An increased demand for our net exports may (or may not, depending on the model and on the central bank's monetary policy) shift the AD curve to the right.

Nick:

One characteristic of market monetarists is that many of us teach undergraduate macro.

It appears another characteristic is that we take the AD-AS model (or framework) seriously.

Does a negative slo[pe] for the AD curve require a constant quantity of money? Not exactly. Constant nominal income does the same. As long as nominal income doesn't change in proportion to the price level there is going to be a negative slope.

Of course, with interest rate targeting, there is exactly that tendency.

Interesting that Market Monetarists are all skeptics/critics of interest rate targeting. That is, critics of what central banks like to do.

What is the key problem with AS-AD? No interest rates on the diagram.

As explained by Dorman, to tell the story that central banks want told, you need interest rates. Sure enough, an exogenous interest rate and IS gives you real expenditures on output. Okun's law gives employment and I suppose unemployment. The output gap version of the philliip's curve gives inflation.

Inflation and unemployment are the political lightning rods that central banks must limit and avoid.

If the goal is to stabilize interest rates subject to the constraint that unemployment and inflation not become unacceptably high, then IS and the Phillips curve makes sense.

If interest rates are not important directly, and only inflation and output gaps are problems, AS and AD is just fine.

You have already shown how AS-AD can be used to show the indeterminacy of interest rate targeting. (And what you do is cause macroeconomic disequilibrium to reverse deviations of the price level from target at best. That doesn't sound very good.

Further, the horizontal aggregate demand curve at the target price level makes it painfully obvious the disastrous consequence of the rule for short run supply shocks.

And, by the way, if you do the price level analysis (rather than use growth rates,) then we can see how it is quite possible to have a 3% growth rate of real output with real output remaining well below potential. Gee, maybe the levels matter.

[edited to fix typo above, because I didn't want that typo to detract from a very good comment. NR]

Nick: "But when we teach economics we are not (or should not be) just teaching about the here and now."

Yes! absolutely!

Interesting comments about the AS curve. As you say, the name Aggregate Supply Curve is often inappropriate. But names matter - yesterday I saw an ad for an on-line casino called "BetFair". It's guaranteed to offer anything but fair odds, but the name conveys somehow both fun (funfair) and equity (fairness).

How do you think the name "aggregate supply" curve affects the way that people perceive and interpret the curve? How does the name matter?

As a micro person, I'd answer the question by saying that calling something a supply curve makes it sound that it can only be moved by fundamental technological changes, and so shifts focus to discussions about productivity or technology, but you might have a different perspective.

"Fetish of the first derivative" is the phrase of the day. Interesting post.

"You get one AD curve if..."

What curve do you get if it targets both inflation and (in an admittedly desultory manner) unemployment?

Bill: excellent comment. I have nothing to add.

Frances: Yes, I think the name does matter. The neat thing about calling something a "Phillips Curve" is that that name doesn't mean anything, so it's open to different interpretations of what causes it. The best name would be: "That curve that is like a Phillips Curve, only in levels not rates of change".

But the LRAS curve gets moved by fundamentals like technology, resources, preferences, market structure, etc. We could think of the LRAS curve as showing all the "real" forces, the AD curve as showing all the "monetary" forces, and the SRAS curve showing how the two interact when prices are slow to adjust.

Alex: thanks! I'm not sure if "fetish of the first derivative" is original with me. I remember someone (Brad DeLong?) saying that the only difference between us and David Hume is that we have switched to talking about the first derivative.

Steve: it can't strictly target both. Because that would mean 2 AD curves (one vertical and one horizontal). But it can target a mixture or weighted average of the two. If it's an average, you get something roughly like a rectangular hyperbola (as with NGDP) except that inflation should be on the vertical axis. If there's some sort of threshhold target ("We target 5% unemployment, unless inflation is over 3%") it's going to be sort of L-shaped.

Bernanke and Frank, Principles of Macro, puts inflation on the vertical. Thoughts? Presumably it was a pedagogical choice with some motivation. "Anchored expectations (of inflation?)"?

@Nick: Thanks!

Nick, Excellent post. My only comment is that one can draw the AD curve as a rectangular hyperbola even if the central bank is not targeting NGDP. For example, suppose the central bank "accommodates" price shocks by stabilizing NGDP, but responds to financial crises by letting NGDP fluctuate.

Nick, why wouldn't an excess of imports over exports shift the AS curve to the right? (And similarly a leftward shift if exports are greater than imports?) I got the idea that GDP is on the horizontal axis, but why just GDP? Why wouldn't you chart all sources of production, including foreign, that a nation's economy consumes. Wouldn't that be closer to the reality? Isn't that really the Aggregate Supply?

This is the Friedman quote on Hume:
We have advanced beyond Hume in two respects only: first, we now have a more secure grasp on the quantitative magnitudes involved: second, we have gone one derivative beyond Hume.

Found here:
http://www.humesociety.org/hs/issues/v15n1/mcgee/mcgee-v15n1.pdf

greg: Let Y be Canadian production, C consumption, I investment, G government spending, X exports, M imports.

There are 3 ways we could do the accounting:

1. Y+M=C+I+G+X (imports add to supply, and exports add to demand).

2. Y+M-X=C+I+G (imports add to supply, exports subtract from supply, the right hand side is call "domestic absorption").

3. Y=C+I+G+X-M (exports add to demand, imports subtract from demand).

All 3 ways are equivalent, and give the same answer (unless you screw something up). None is wrong. But 3 is the conventional way of doing it, and it's normally easier if everyone speaks the same language. Plus, if we are especially interested in Y, because Y is also income, then it's easier to see what happens to Y if we put Y on the axis. Plus, this means that the sort of things that shift AS (things like resources and productivity) are very different from the sort of things that shift AD, so it's easier to use the framework.

John: well, if you want to talk about inflation targeting, and if you want to assume the central bank follows a Taylor Rule (which gives the AD curve a downward slope in that space if the central bank falsely assumes the natural rate never changes) then that is probably the easier way to do it.

Scott: thanks! But I think I disagree with your comment. In principle, we could draw the AD curve any shape we want, but have the central bank shift AD in different ways in response to different shocks. But I don't think it's useful to do that. The whole point of drawing a curve is to find the right curve so that it doesn't shift much, or only shifts in a limited number of cases. For example, if the bank targets NGDP, then it's best to draw a rectangular hyperbola AD curve, because then the AD curve will only shift if: the bank changes its target; the bank screws it up.

Wonks: (I just rescued your comment from the spam filter.)

So it was Friedman, and not Brad DeLong. Shows how bad my memory is. I really should have remembered that. Thanks.

Nick:

I sure don't do this in class, but I like your idea that the shape of the AD curve depends on the monetary regime.

I draw negatively sloped AD curves and shift them around.

By the way, with a gold standard, AD is negatively sloped, right?

Bill: I think so yes. For a small open economy, under fixed exchange rates, the slope of the AD is determined by the elasticity of net exports wrt the real exchange rate (plus a few other things, depending on the model). I think the AD for the world economy on the gold standard would also slope down, but I would have to think a bit to figure out what determines the slope. Something to do with the elasticity of demand and supply for gold.

OK, Nick, so I've been looking at it from No. 2: Y+M-X=C+I+G. I'm trying to get this point of view. So set M>X, and simplify by ignoring I and G. So C>Y. But I don't get from this equation that the price level goes down along the AD curve, which, other things being equal, seems to me what should happen, since the aggregate supply increases. (AS curve shifts to right.) And if the price level goes down...so does the income of domestic producers, since they are still producing at the original AS curve. (Real domestic production does not change, with vertical AS curve.)

greg: start with M=X. Now increase M holding C, I, G, and X constant. In approach 3, AD shifts left, so P goes down.

Real domestic production and real domestic income (measured in terms of domestically-produced goods) stay the same, if the AS curve is vertical. But domestic income falls in dollar terms, since P falls.

Nick: Yeah, I get that. So it would be deflationary. And if the AS curve curved to the left at a lower price level, a la Keynes, running a trade deficit would be contractionary, too.

Now start with M=X. Now increase X holding C, I, G, and M constant. In approach 3, AD shifts right, so P goes up.

The comments to this entry are closed.

Search this site

  • Google

    WWW
    worthwhile.typepad.com
Blog powered by Typepad