Scott Sumner and Bill Woolsey have been fighting valiantly against the Austrians. The fight is about "Cantillon effects" -- non-neutralities of money that are supposed to arise not from the increase in the money supply itself but from where exactly that new money enters the economy.
Sometimes you get a clearer answer to a question if you change the question. That's what I'm going to do here.
Let's stop asking whether the effect of a change in the level of the money supply depends on where that new stock of money enters the economy. Instead, let's assume the money supply is growing at a constant rate, and ask whether it matters where that constant flow of new money enters the economy. We are simply redirecting that constant flow of new money, not changing the stock and redirecting it at the same time. It's easier to keep our heads straight that way.
1% of GDP isn't peanuts. But it's not very big either. And I've stacked my assumptions to make it bigger than it would be in most normal economies. If NGDP is growing at 5% per year, and base money is 5% of NGDP, the flow of new money would be 0.25% of NGDP.
I will assume the government owns the central bank. Any profit the central bank gets from printing money is government revenue. We can consolidate the government's and central bank's balance sheets, so any interest the government pays on bonds owned by the central bank is a wash. The government is paying that interest to itself. The central bank earns profits of 1% of GDP, and gives those profits to the government, which decides how to spend them.
Let's compare 5 different ways the same flow of new money could enter the economy.
1. Interest on money. The baseline scenario is that all new money is paid as interest on existing money. So every year people earn 10% interest on their money, which exactly offsets the 10% depreciation through inflation. It's a wash. It's really just like a stock-split.
2. Helicopter money. Scenario 2 is that all new money is paid as transfers to the population. It's no different from scenario 1, except that the opportunity cost of holding base money is higher (because it depreciates through inflation but doesn't pay interest), so the real stock of money would be smaller. (Plus some individuals might get lucky and others unlucky depending on whether the helicopter does or does not fly over them.)
2a. Cut taxes. The government uses the new money to cut taxes. Same as scenario 2. A tax is a negative transfer payment. So a tax cut is a transfer increase.
3. Debt reduction. Scenario 3 is that all new money is handed over to the government, which uses it to retire government bonds. Scenario 3 is the same as an open market purchase of bonds by the central bank. Scenario 3 is identical to scenario 2, plus a tax of 1% of GDP used to pay down the debt. Does it matter if the government increases taxes to pay down debt?
4. Government spending. Scenario 4 is that all new money is handed over to the government, which uses it to buy goods. Scenario 4 is identical to scenario 2, plus a tax of 1% of GDP used to buy goods. Does it matter if the government increases taxes and spending? Obviously it matters whether the government buys bridges or schools or roads or whatever. One gives us more bridges and the other gives us more schools, or roads, or whatever.
5. Other financial assets. Scenario 5 is that all new money is used to buy some other financial asset, like shares in IBM. Since the government owns the central bank, it doesn't matter if it is the government or the central bank that buys the IBM shares. Scenario 5 is identical to scenario 2, plus a tax used to buy IBM shares. Scenario 5 is also identical to scenario 3, plus a bond-financed purchase of IBM shares. Does a bond-financed purchase of IBM shares matter? I expect it depends on how close substitutes the two assets are in people's portfolios.
Sorry. What was the question again? Was it: "Do Cantillon effects matter?" Or was it "Does fiscal policy matter?" I can't tell the difference. There is no difference. "Cantillon effects" are just another name for "the effects of fiscal policy".
OK. I suppose that Austrian economists believe that fiscal policy matters. I suppose it does. And monetary policy has fiscal implications, because a faster growth rate of the money supply will mean bigger seigniorage profits for the government (as long as we stay on the left side of the Laffer Curve).
But the size of those fiscal implications depends on the ratio of the monetary base to nominal GDP.
In Canada, non-interest paying currency is currently around 4% of nominal GDP. An increase in the inflation target from the current 2% to 12% would mean a 10 ppt increase in the growth rate of the money supply. That would be a very big change in monetary policy. Even if the currency/NGDP ratio stayed the same at 4% (it would fall), the fiscal implications of that very big monetary policy change would be 0.4% of GDP.
What do you think would be the bigger deal: increasing the inflation target from 2% to 12%, or changing taxes or government spending by 0.4% of GDP?
[Update: hoisted from comments. J. V. Dubois says:
"You guys really do not get the gist of what Nick is saying?
1. Seigniorage of government controlled money IS TAX on base money
2. "Where" and how much of newly printed money is injected - even if that has any effect on redistribution IS FISCAL POLICY.
If you say that it makes a great deal of difference (deforming long-term capital structure etc) if money is injected into salaries of government employees vs purchase of bonds, then you by the same argument think that it makes a great deal of difference if government decides that from now on it spends 0.25% of GDP gathered in taxes on one versus another.
If you for instance say that Bond Dealers gather undue profits from these bond operations of the size of 0.25% GDP - then by the same account you have to be outraged that those very same bond dealers gather undue profits from regular yearly government deficits an order of magnitude higher. It is a problem of interest group capturing government and preventing competition from access to the bond market, it is not a problem of money printing."]
The only Cantillon Effects that much interests Hayek are those that change the stock of shadow monies/money substitutes and lengthen the structure of production in an non-sustainable fashion.
It's really essential to get this effect to assume an ever increasing percentage rise in the domain of money, credit and shadow monies/money substitutes.
At least if you are engaging the guy who did the work to build the 'Austrian' picture of this.
Posted by: Greg Ransom | December 04, 2012 at 11:35 PM
"We are simply redirecting that constant flow of new money,"
OK.
Randomly, and with no notice of any kind, on day 1 we redirect that money into the purchase of Mortgage Backed Securities.
Randomly and with no notice of any kind on day 2,000 we cut of that flow of money and redirect that money into the purchase of back rubs.
The point of the exercise, I assume, is to illustrate a systematic structural dis-coordination across the time and production and price structure of the economy, including the interest rate price.
What do you think?
Think we have a wrenching disconnect in the time structure of production here?
If not, why not.
Posted by: Greg Ransom | December 04, 2012 at 11:48 PM
Greg: suppose we increased taxes, and used it to buy MBS, or backrubs. Would that also create a wrenching disconnect in the time structure of production?
Posted by: Nick Rowe | December 04, 2012 at 11:54 PM
This "where" business is just short language for forced savings allowing for longer production processes promising superior output induced by an interest rate which has fallen below the interest rate possible via the sustainable savings rate.
Ie its snowballing endogeneous money in the banking system & shadow money credit backing investment in long term production goods like houses.
The "where" is the houses, the financial system. Yes, the Fed can have a role, even a primary role. But the same process is possible without a central bank, or can be do to "money from China", etc.
Nick writes,
"The fight is about "Cantillon effects" -- non-neutralities of money that are supposed to arise not from the increase in the money supply itself but from where exactly that new money enters the economy."
Posted by: Greg Ransom | December 05, 2012 at 12:00 AM
Here's a Google NGRAM of 'neutral money' and "forced savings'.
You'll see them explode in the English literature at the same time, at the time of Hayek's famous 1931 LSE lectures published as Prices and Production:
http://books.google.com/ngrams/graph?content=neutral+money%2C+forced+savings&year_start=1800&year_end=2000&corpus=15&smoothing=1&share=
Non-neutral money and forced savings were linked concepts at the time.
If I remember right, it's Hayek also who goes through the history of economic thought of all this for the English economists for the first time, going through Hume and Cantillon etc on neutral money and Cantillon Effects and Bentham and others on forced savings.
Here's an NGRAM for 'neutral money and 'Cantillon'. You see that same 1931 explosion:
http://books.google.com/ngrams/graph?content=neutral+money%2Ccantillon+effects&year_start=1800&year_end=2000&corpus=15&smoothing=1&share=
Hayek introduced Cantillon and Cantillon Effects in order to open the door for English economists to think about interest rate and money and credit induced extensions of more lengthy production processes promising superior output -- the Bohm-Bawerk stuff assumed in Wicksell that British economists didn't know anything about.
Posted by: Greg Ransom | December 05, 2012 at 12:12 AM
Nick writes,
"Greg: suppose we increased taxes, and used it to buy MBS, or backrubs. Would that also create a wrenching disconnect in the time structure of production?"
The question is, how wouldn't it?
Lets go to a more stark thought experiment.
In case #1 we use all of our income (except what is required to eat carrots) to create ever more complex and massive computerized and mechanized fish farms.
In case #2 we used all of our income (except what is required to eat carrots) to pay individuals to catch fish by hand.
Imagine by fiat that we switched from case #1 to case #2.
Basically, all of the capital goods used to produce the production goods required to make the fish farms would lose their economic goods status.
All of the worker would be skilled in all of various tasks required to create the production goods for the fish farms, but wouldn't know how to fish with their hands.
Anything case #1 good potentially salvageable that might help a guy fishing with his hands would have to be converted for that use, requiring labor and perhaps the creation of other, new production goods.
We can imagine that the production goods eventually supporting fishing with your hands might develop in sophistication over time, but that would take time.
Posted by: Greg Ransom | December 05, 2012 at 12:32 AM
So...Sheldon Richman was right, and Scott Sumner should apologize? I don't get the sense that's what you're trying to say, Nick.
It's as if Jesse Jackson says, "It matters whether the police shoot at a fleeing bank robber vs. an innocent teenager!"
Then the NYPD chief says, "No it really really really doesn't matter."
People flip out, and then the NYPD chief (and his Canadian lawyer) elaborate, "Oh, we were assuming we were talking about scenarios in which the bullets all miss their targets. When they actually *hit*, we don't classify that as 'shooting,' we classify that as 'hitting.' You whiners need to use standardized nomenclature before you complain next time."
Posted by: Bob Murphy | December 05, 2012 at 12:32 AM
Dear Greg, unlike e-mail and like most prose, in most parts of the Internet it is conventional to put the quoted passage before the text you are replying to. Also, you may find the <blockquote></blockquote> tags useful, both on here and on Sumner's blog.
I mean, you do write and quote liberally, no offense.
Posted by: david | December 05, 2012 at 12:35 AM
Ah... before the text to you are writing as a reply. Brain fart.
Posted by: david | December 05, 2012 at 12:38 AM
Nick writes,
"Greg: suppose we increased taxes, and used it to buy MBS, or backrubs. Would that also create a wrenching disconnect in the time structure of production?"
Didn't the Soviet Union already run this experiment?
This is one reason some people supported the Soviet model -- the state could accelerate growth & wealth via *direct* forced savings, ie redirecting resources into lengthier production processes promising superior output -- for example giant steel mills & imported 40 year Scotch for Stalin -- rather than into shorter production process goods inferior output -- neighborhood iron black smiths, cut flowers, back rubs, and vodka.
And when the forces savings regime came to an end -- wrenching disconnect in the structure of production.
Posted by: Greg Ransom | December 05, 2012 at 12:44 AM
One more on this.
Nick writes,
"Greg: suppose we increased taxes, and used it to buy MBS, or backrubs. Would that also create a wrenching disconnect in the time structure of production?"
In the US we in part ran this experiment in housing over the last decade, via all sort of unsustainable and effectively yo-yoing government policies helping to direct resources into the long term production good of housing.
The big issue is when you make changes that turn highly productive long period production goods into non-economic goods or into production goods re-purposed in processes producing far less income and value or into goods that perhaps can be used, once someone discovers or invents a use for them.
Consider the hundreds of miles of moth balled lumber rail cars parked across the United States in the wake of the construction crash.
Arnold Kling make a similar point about specialized labor.
When you suddenly cut off various streams of every longer production processes, the effect is different than when you gradually add to streams of gradually lengthening production processes.
The former and not the later suddenly throws production goods into non-economic goods status.
Posted by: Greg Ransom | December 05, 2012 at 01:03 AM
Nick,
I'd argue that 1 is actually contractionary because the nominal short rate will have to go to 10% (otherwise people wod borrow and hold currency).
2 is quite different because it principally constitutes a wealth transfer from creditors to debtors. Since debtors tend to be credit constrained, this is strongly stimulative.
4 is similar to 2. The money gets spent.
3 and 5 do nothing (Wallace irrelevance)
Posted by: K | December 05, 2012 at 01:07 AM
people *would* borrow...
Posted by: K | December 05, 2012 at 01:11 AM
Examples of long term production goods becoming non-economics goods -- VIDEO of nearly completed homes being bulldozed in Southern California in 2009:
http://abclocal.go.com/kabc/story?section=news/local/inland_empire&id=6797624
http://www.nbclosangeles.com/the-scene/real-estate/Developers_Bulldoze_Empty_Luxury_Homes_in_Victorville_Los_Angeles.html
Posted by: Greg Ransom | December 05, 2012 at 01:25 AM
Here is a photo of some of those mothballed lumber rail cars in North America:
http://archive.mises.org/13572/seeing-is-believing-20-miles-of-empty-and-mothballed-lumber-hauling-rail-cars/
I personally drove past 20 miles of them in 2010.
Posted by: Greg Ransom | December 05, 2012 at 01:27 AM
How would you analyze the FDR gold devaluation, or a modern day exchange rate intervention? Surely they aren't neutral, since prices don't automatically and uniformly increase in response.
Posted by: Max | December 05, 2012 at 02:02 AM
Nick
This is a fair typolocy, however, the question remains - do you agree with Scott's definition of 'holding fiscal policy constant'?
If you do, then I suppose, when a typical central banker talks of easing monetary policy through govt. bond purchases, what he's really doing is easing monetary policy + tightening fiscal policy?
Corollary is, that the only 'true' monetary policy, one where fiscal policy is held 'constant' is a helicopter drop. Or, all money is helicopter money.
Is the above a fair parsing?
Posted by: Ritwik | December 05, 2012 at 07:11 AM
Nick:
Excellent post.
I think the core Austrian view is that an excess supply of money causes the market interest rate to fall below the natural interest rate, and that the lower market interest rate impacts the allocation of resources similar to a lower natural interest rate due to an increase in the supply of saving.
When one begins to challenge these arguments (which I think are qualitatively correct,) many of the responses imply that the equilibrium effects you describe are being balled up with the disequilibirum process.
This would be most blantant with the AAN group (Amateur Austrians of the Net.) For example, if the inflation doesn't lead to malinvestment, then it must be that counterfeiters gain nothing. Well, counterfeiters gain something, and pretty much everything even when there is no disequilibrium.
If the government is the "counterfeiter" and so we characterize the gain as a type of tax revenue (seignorage) then this does come down to "fiscal policy" in the broadest since, as you suggest. Though I think that perhaps "public finance" is a better way to look at it, since "fiscal policy" is often used to mean something more narrow--changing taxes or government spending, the budnget deficit, and so aggregate demand.
Posted by: Bill Woolsey | December 05, 2012 at 07:25 AM
Nick,
Scott Sumner never addressed this question I raised on his blog - perhaps you'd like to take a crack at it...
Assuming a Sumnerian world, why do banks consent to transactions with the Central Bank? What's it in it for them? I think I am at the point where I understand what Sumner is suggesting about the macroeconomy, but if he is correct then it would seem to suggest to me that banks have no good incentive to deal with the Central Bank at all.
Posted by: RPLong | December 05, 2012 at 08:10 AM
You guys really do not get the gist of what Nick is saying?
1. Seigniorage of government controlled money IS TAX on base money
2. "Where" and how much of newly printed money is injected - even if that has any effect on redistribution IS FISCAL POLICY.
If you say that it makes a great deal of difference (deforming long-term capital structure etc) if money is injected into salaries of government employees vs purchase of bonds, then you by the same argument think that it makes a great deal of difference if government decides that from now on it spends 0.25% of GDP gathered in taxes on one versus another.
If you for instance say that Bond Dealers gather undue profits from these bond operations of the size of 0.25% GDP - then by the same account you have to be outraged that those very same bond dealers gather undue profits from regular yearly government deficits an order of magnitude higher. It is a problem of interest group capturing government and preventing competition from access to the bond market, it is not a problem of money printing.
Posted by: J.V. Dubois | December 05, 2012 at 08:10 AM
RPLong:
If I offer a bank a $100 bill in return for $100 worth of bonds, why wouldn't they agree to the trade? Especially if I threw in a few extra cents of commission?
Posted by: Alex Godofsky | December 05, 2012 at 08:52 AM
Bob: In all except maybe scenario 5 (where the government sells bonds to purchase IBM shares) I am using an absolutely standard definition of fiscal policy. Changing G and/or T. But 5 is just the government buying shares on margin, which is something that a lot of people do every day.
Why does fiscal policy, or somebody buying IBM shares on margin, cause a total discombobulation in the Hayekian time structure of production?
And if it does cause a discombobulation in the time structure of production, why aren't Austrians yelling about that every time the government changes G or T by 0.4% of GDP? Or somebody buys IBM shares on margin?
Man, but you Austrian guys must think the market economy is an awfully fragile flower.
Posted by: Nick Rowe | December 05, 2012 at 08:56 AM
Nick, I of course agree that fiscal differences matter. I was discussing the Austrian view that if the central bank buys injects money by buying bonds, it depends who they buy them from. But fiscal policy is the same whether the bonds are purchased from person A or person B. I assume you agree with that. Appearently some Austrians don't.
Posted by: Scott Sumner | December 05, 2012 at 09:03 AM
Ah. I see that JV Dubois gets it, and has said it better than me.
Posted by: Nick Rowe | December 05, 2012 at 09:04 AM
Scott: we are very much on the same page, I think.
Posted by: Nick Rowe | December 05, 2012 at 09:09 AM
Bill: "Though I think that perhaps "public finance" is a better way to look at it, since "fiscal policy" is often used to mean something more narrow--changing taxes or government spending, the budnget deficit, and so aggregate demand."
Yep. Good point. And thanks!
Posted by: Nick Rowe | December 05, 2012 at 09:16 AM
Nick,
I think Cantillion effects can be considered as follows:
Liquidity preference - The first injection of money can be considered to be by an agent that has a liquidity preference of 0 (all of the money is spent). As the money then propogates through the economy it encounters resistance (liquidity preference greater than 0) by each agent that it passes through.
"An increase in the inflation target from the current 2% to 12% would mean a 10 ppt increase in the growth rate of the money supply."
Remember your discussion of cartels. The central bank is a cartel, but it cannot try to control two things at once. It can target the growth of money supply and let interest rates float or it can target the interest rate and let the growth of money supply float. An increase in the inflation target from 2% to 12% targets neither the interest rate nor the growth rate of the money supply. And so a central bank can create an inflation target, but it has no means of enforcing that target.
MV = PQ
It does not matter what the central bank does in terms of reserves, they could print a quadrillion dollars that never sees the light of day and would have no effect on the economy. Money begins as a debt and so we rewrite M as D.
DV = PQ
PQ is the nominal value of all goods that are purchased. They can be purchased out of unsaved current income or they can be purchased with new debt.
DV = I * (1 - LP) + dD/dt : Liqidity preference (LP)
Income (I) is the sum of interest payments made on debt and the sale of goods (PQ)
DV = ( INT * D + PQ )*( 1 - LP ) + dD/dt
PQ = DV
DV = ( INT * D + DV ) * ( 1 - LP ) + dD/dt
D = exp ( f(t) ) - f(t) is the demand for new money (debt)
dD/dt = f'(t) * exp( f(t) )
V * LP = INT * ( 1 - LP) + f'(t)
V = INT * ( 1 - LP ) / LP + f'(t) / LP
Plugging this expression for V back into our equation:
D * [ INT * ( 1 - LP ) / LP + f'(t) / LP ] = PQ
PQ can be re-expressed as Real GDP * ( 1 + Inflation Rate )
INT can be re-expressed as the Real Interest Rate + Inflation Rate
D * [ ( RINT + IR ) * ( 1 - LP ) / LP + f'(t) / LP ] = RGDP * ( 1 + IR )
[ ( RINT + IR ) * ( 1 - LP ) / LP + f'(t) / LP ] / ( 1 + IR ) = RGDP / D
Productivity can be expressed as Real GDP / Debt
[ ( RINT + IR ) * ( 1 - LP ) / LP + f'(t) / LP ] / ( 1 + IR ) = PROD
Solving for the rate of inflation:
IR * ( 1 - LP ) / LP - IR * PROD = PROD - f'(t) / LP - RINT * ( 1 - LP ) / LP
IR = [ LP * PROD - f'(t) - RINT * ( 1 - LP )] / [ 1 - LP - LP * PROD ]
And so the inflation rate is not strictly the growth rate in the money supply (credit supply). It is a function that is dependent on several variables. The inflation rate depends on:
Productivity (PROD)
Real Interest Rate (RINT)
Liquidity Preference (LP)
Credit Demand (f(t))
Posted by: Frank Restly | December 05, 2012 at 09:45 AM
Nick, JVD
Let's agree with what you're saying.
So, the fiscal impact of an OMO is similar/analogous to the fiscal impact of raising taxes to pay out bondholders.
Ergo, an OMO = helicopter drop + transfer of seigniorage revenues to bondholders.
Agree/disagree?
Posted by: Ritwik | December 05, 2012 at 09:55 AM
Ritwik: disagree. Slightly.
OMO purchase of bonds = helicopter drop + tax increase to purchase bonds.
A tax increase to purchase bonds isn't the same as a transfer payment to bondholders. The government is *buying* bonds from them, not *giving* them a transfer payment.
Posted by: Nick Rowe | December 05, 2012 at 10:17 AM
Max: sure. Prices are sticky. So changing the money supply has real effects. But that is true quite apart from Cantillon effects.
Posted by: Nick Rowe | December 05, 2012 at 10:21 AM
>>You guys really do not get the gist of what Nick is saying?
1. Seigniorage of government controlled money IS TAX on base money
2. "Where" and how much of newly printed money is injected - even if that has any effect on redistribution IS FISCAL POLICY.<<
Forced savings -- unsustainable lengthening of production processes promising superior output -- is 'fiscal policy'.
I get it.
But it isn't done by the legislature, and doesn't even have to be a product of a central bank.
Odd.
Posted by: Greg Ransom | December 05, 2012 at 10:36 AM
Nick,
It seems to me that everyone is confused! What I *would* agree with is that monetary policy (getting the real rate close to the natural rate) is the only efficient way to regulate the macroeconomy, and the differences between the different scenarios above relate to how they effect fiscal policy in addition to how they may or may not be implementing monetary policy.
The problem is that the model economy on which you've based your five examples bears no structural relation to a modern pure credit economy so the illustrative effect is totally lost on me. E.g. the first example doesn't produce anything like 10% inflation in the economy. Lets say you suddenly start to pay 10% interest on currency. All short lending rates will immediately rise to 10%+ (by arbitrage). Inflation expectations will *plummet* as consumers attempt to hoard cash and preserve savings. Demand for new loans will drop, loan repayments will skyrocket and bank balance sheets will collapse as a result. The monetary base does not figure as a relevant variable in the explanation. If you wanted to do your experiment you'd have to convert to a purely electronic currency. But to achieve the inflation you are looking for you'd have to *cut*, not raise the rate you pay on the currency.
So while I kind of agree with your main point (I think), your examples would be more helpful/convincing if they were set in a framework that behaved more like the one we live in.
[Somewhat OT...]
One thing that rarely seems to be discussed is *why* the free market can't get the real rate right all by itself. Why is there this one price in the market that the government has to set? (Austrians surely disagree?) It seems to me that the problem is that the monetary authority determines the nominal rate. And the dynamics of inflation expectations (Keynesian coordination problem) are such that they don't move up and down in parallel with the nominal rate (in fact they move in the opposite direction) and therefore the monetary authority determines the real rate (which is tough because it's like driving backwards with a trailer). Which, I guess, is why the CB should be setting NGDP futures and not rates (no trailer *and* driving forwards looking out the front window).
Then the question (to get somewhat back on topic) is whether setting NGDP futures would be more efficient (less "fiscal") than setting rates. The answer is that whatever policy is likely to get the real rate closer to the natural rate is the most efficient. NGDP futures wins hands down.
Posted by: K | December 05, 2012 at 10:43 AM
Alex,
Good point. So then you must agree with me that the banks experience a direct and significant advantage to dealing with the central monetary authority. Could it be that these advantages - to which the financial sector has access, but the rest of us do not - are precisely what the "Austrians" are talking about?
Posted by: RPLong | December 05, 2012 at 11:07 AM
K:
If money paid 10% interest and there is no RGDP growth, in the Long Run you really really do get 10% inflation. I think that is Nick's claim.
Posted by: Alex Godofsky | December 05, 2012 at 11:11 AM
Nick
So, you agree with Scott that CB bond purchases don't affect bond prices?
Posted by: Ritwik | December 05, 2012 at 11:12 AM
RPLong:
No, because the advantage is really, really small compared to the scale of Fed activity (and invisible compared to the scale of the whole economy). You are talking about, what, a few tens of millions of dollars a year in what are basically administrative fees?
Posted by: Alex Godofsky | December 05, 2012 at 11:14 AM
Nick, we already know the market is 'fragile' -- the problem raising pattern is what starts the process of conceiving the processes and mechanisms which make the *fact* possible.
We can conceived perfect plan coordination in our head building an equilibrium construct.
What is the 'loose joint' which allows the system the flexibility which is *already* observed?
We are dealing with a complex system, and not with a two variable linear action, reaction relation between eg billiard balls.
So we go looking for what the philosopher of explanation Larry Wright calls 'trace data' -- suggestive hints that play two roles. The help us conceive what the process is, and they later make up elements of the explanation of the original problem to be explained.
So what are some of the trace data?
Well, the big one is extra-ordinary fluctuations in monies, credit, interest rates, finance, shadow money, money substitute asset values, liquidity, etc.
See here:
http://hayekcenter.org/?p=2954
And it turns out we can identify how banking and finance tied in various ways to the rest of the economy can yo-yo price relations and the availability of means of exchange -- money can be 'endogenously' created and vaporized within the financial sector, tied in important ways to flexibilities in the production and consumption economy, eg to expanding resources into longer production processes which take time to expose their profitability or loss making, or contracting these.
So we have complex process capable of providing the 'loose joint' required from the observed fragility of the economy.
Is that all there is to the fragility?
No.
We haven't yet introduced central banks, or pathological financial regulations, or national currency laws, or insolvent nations, or international monetary economics, money contracts, or, well, you get the idea.
The 'loose joint' explanation is an 'ultimate cause', its at the core of a complex explanation.
But explaining the *size* and *duration* and *scope* and *historical character* of a fragility episode brings in all sorts of other proximate causes, eg Milton Friedman's account the causal effects of the deflationary policies of the Fed, the role of the Smoot-Hawley tariff in crashing agricultural and the effect of that on crashing US banks banned from practicing national branch banking, expansions of unemployment insurance, fixed money contracts & other 'sticky price' barriers to system flexibility and future oriented expectational coordination.
Usually, economists misread Hayek's seminal essays "Economics and Knowledge" and "The Use of Knowledge in Society". They claim Hayek assumes Arrow's picture of the 'invisible hand' -- its magic instant coordination jumping right off the math of the GET. That's not Hayek. Hayek's whole lesson in those essays, learned from looking at the real world problem of coordinating production choice across time in the literature on central planning and business cycles -- is that coordination is bottom up groping in the dark using only local knowledge and limited understanding of trace elements of the relation of networks of prices.
The market isn't the magic of a GE construct and its isn't a delicate flower -- its a hard won marvel with a loose joint -- a loose joint which often has monkey wrenches thrown it for good measure by folks who do not understand the complex process and how it has degrees of freedom that allow it to move here and there to some degree in directions that are unsustainable and that required period episodes of re-coordination.
Posted by: Greg Ransom | December 05, 2012 at 11:22 AM
The reason I'm talking about bond prices and a transfer of seigniorage is - you can think of the raised taxes to finance the bond purchases as being *drawn against* the seigniorage power of freshly issued money, and the govt reducing supply/ CB increasing demand (stock/flow/whatever) for govvies pushes up their price.
Do you disagree that there will be an increase in prices?
Scott argues that there's no increase in the price, fiscal policy held 'constant'. My contention was that he was using a funny definition of fiscal policy held constant.
Similarly, if the CB was to inject fresh money through govt employee salaries, it would be a transfer of seigniorage revenues (or, taxes, take your pick really) to government employees.
So, the only case of *money injection* that's fiscally *neutral* is a helicopter drop.
Agree/disagree?
Posted by: Ritwik | December 05, 2012 at 11:23 AM
The other major 'trace data' we see in the problem raising pattern of 'fragility' we have in front of us I've already pointed to, the production goods were are bulldozed and mothballed, the 1/4 of all unemployed early in the US bust of the 2000s who were construction workers, etc.
Posted by: Greg Ransom | December 05, 2012 at 11:28 AM
Alex,
I agree that the macroeconomic impact of the benefits that we both agree exist is small when compared to the overall impact on the economy at large.
I disagree that this small impact "makes no difference." If I can make money on the deal being offered, then it makes a difference to me. If the Fed or the Bank of Canada truly have the macroeconomy in mind, then shouldn't they devise a new form of monetary policy that does not enable a certain segment of the population to make millions while the rest of us deal only with inflation, without the benefit of the millions in profits that come with having private access to the machinery of fiscal policy?
In short, if it "makes no difference," then it is all the more unconscionable that only a few of us have access to these transactions. Wouldn't you agree with Milton Friedman that a literal helicopter drop or a computerized interest rate adjustment would be superior?
Posted by: RPLong | December 05, 2012 at 11:34 AM
RPLong, this is like complaining about the fat-cat toilet paper companies that stock the Fed's bathrooms. If the Fed wants to buy a billion dollars worth of bonds it is impractical for them to go door-to-door asking individuals if they have any for sale.
Posted by: Alex Godofsky | December 05, 2012 at 11:46 AM
K,
"And the dynamics of inflation expectations (Keynesian coordination problem) are such that they don't move up and down in parallel with the nominal rate (in fact they move in the opposite direction) and therefore the monetary authority determines the real rate (which is tough because it's like driving backwards with a trailer)."
The monetary authority is limited by the 0% lower bound for nominal interest rates. Meaning that during severe deflation, the real interest rate can keep rising even when the monetary authority has set nominal interest rates to 0%.
The monetary authority can only set nominal interest rates.
Posted by: Frank Restly | December 05, 2012 at 11:47 AM
K
"Why is there this one price in the market that the government has to set?"
Various explanations exist.
1) If you think of this rate as the risk-free short rate, Geanakoplos et al have shown that a market GE doesn't converge on the socially optimal numeraire, leaving government as the authority to set the rate on the financial numeraire (and tying that up with the consumption numeraire through a consistent price regime).
2) If you think of this rate as the risky cost of capital, one can take the Keynesian (circa Treatise of Money) view that financiers will set this too high purely as a matter of convention i.e. adaptive expectations make the LM curve horizontal-ish.
3) If you think of some combination of 1 and 2, or the risk premium, you can take the view that this is subject to socially sub-optimal volatility (ch12 Keynes). You can even take the Schumpeterian view that the risk premium is too high secularly through-out history and it's only because of the bankers, the capitalists par excellence, that we've managed to make any progress. In this view, the government steps in to solve the market risk premium problem every time that the financial system refuses to.
4) You could take the Gesell/Keynes/Marx view that the short risk-free rate is in some sense reflective of the relative power of the moneyed interest and the non-moneyed masses, and hence (my interpretation)the morally correct risk free real rate is 0%, which the community/government imposes.
5) Through some combination of 1,2,3,4 you could argue that the government's main commercial role is to act as an inter-temporal insurer that chooses the superior wealth equilibria in a sequence of choices between multiple equilibria, aided by the fact that it is unconstrained by the profit motive, has no liquidity constriant and a fairly flexible budget consraint. I'd imagine that this role could be shown to be isomorphic to setting the yield curve, or assuming efficient markets, the short rate.
There are big information and public choice issues, of course, as with any government activity. But the pure theory of public finance as exerting control on real interest rates is probably on rather solid grounds.
Posted by: Ritwik | December 05, 2012 at 11:48 AM
Alex Godofsky,
"If money paid 10% interest and there is no RGDP growth, in the Long Run you really really do get 10% inflation."
I don't agree. You are setting a permanent 10% nominal short rate. That is not a stable equilibrium, ever. So you will either be in debt-deflation or hyper-inflation. You may switch between them, especially from debt-deflation to inflation. And that's just in a sensible model economy. Meanwhile, back in the real world, if you manage the currency like that it will be abandoned as money pretty quickly, so there wont be any Long Run for that currency.
Posted by: K | December 05, 2012 at 11:48 AM
K:
Yup, you're right, I retract the earlier claim.
Posted by: Alex Godofsky | December 05, 2012 at 11:49 AM
You market monetarists are something else, Nick. Scott writes a post titled "It really really really doesn't matter..." (yes, three "really"s by him in the title), and now the burden of proof is on me to show that the economy would have a boom-bust cycle because of Cantillon effects?
Scott dodged this question when I asked, Nick, so please tell me your answer: In normal times (not when we're up against ZLB), if the Fed decides to cut short-term interest rates and buys Treasuries, do you agree that this really does push down short-term interest rates (raise price of short-term safe bonds)? You can give whatever caveats you want, but I want to understand what power you think the central bank has over the market price of bonds, if any.
Posted by: Bob Murphy | December 05, 2012 at 11:50 AM
Alex, I would only agree with your analogy if buying toilet paper were the Fed's preferred monetary policy instrument.
Posted by: RPLong | December 05, 2012 at 11:56 AM
Think of it this way:
When the fed buys bonds from specific people, they receive two things: (1) all the same monetary policy affects we do, and (2) a direct profit that can be reinvested as a hedge against inflation, which they only receive because they do business with the Fed.
Me, on the other hand: I get (1) but I do not get (2).
Posted by: RPLong | December 05, 2012 at 12:00 PM
Alex Godofsky,
You're a noble man. I endeavor to be as magnanimous.
Posted by: K | December 05, 2012 at 12:01 PM
RPLong:
Yes, and when the Fed employs specific people, they receive two things: (1) ..., and (2) a salary. But I don't complain bitterly about how Ben Bernanke is getting rich off my tax dollars, and why can't we ALL get salaries from the Fed, etc. The profit the banks make on the transaction is just the normal compensation any business receives for providing a service.
Posted by: Alex Godofsky | December 05, 2012 at 12:06 PM
Ritwik,
Really excellent, interesting comment (but perhaps too OT for me to respond to most of it). Your explanation #1 sounds like my perspective: a) Someone has to establish a common numeraire (unit of account), b) controlling that numeraire means controlling the risk-free nominal short rate c) controlling the nominal short rate also means controlling the real short rate because inflation expectations move in the opposite direction of the nominal short rate (this last bit is at the core of what's so horribly wrong with the entire RBC literature). Since the monetary authority inevitably sets the real rate, they don't have a choice but to have a monetary policy.
Posted by: K | December 05, 2012 at 12:24 PM
Here's Sheldon Richman's original article (it is only now online).
Posted by: Bob Murphy | December 05, 2012 at 01:02 PM
Bob: Long run (flexible prices): if a central bank permanently loosens monetary policy by raising the inflation target (increasing the money growth rate), nominal bond prices will fall.
Short run (sticky prices): if the central bank temporarily loosens monetary policy, but leaves the long run target unchanged, nominal bond prices may rise.
Posted by: Nick Rowe | December 05, 2012 at 01:17 PM
"Man, but you Austrian guys must think the market economy is an awfully fragile flower."
Tyler Cowen made a similar point here:
http://marginalrevolution.com/marginalrevolution/2008/01/the-return-of-h.html
Posted by: Wonks Anonymous | December 05, 2012 at 01:37 PM
I'm also reminded of Noah Smith's point that the "PSST"/"recalculation" view of the economy is one where the "invisible hand" doesn't seem to do its work:
http://noahpinionblog.blogspot.com/2011/05/note-i-wrote-this-post-quite-while-ago.html
Posted by: Wonks Anonymous | December 05, 2012 at 01:40 PM
Alex, you said: "Yes, and when the Fed employs specific people, they receive two things: (1) ..., and (2) a salary. But I don't complain bitterly about how Ben Bernanke is getting rich off my tax dollars, and why can't we ALL get salaries from the Fed, etc."
But surely you know that there are large numbers of people who do see government salaries as being paid at the expense of hard-working ordinary people? Just because you don't sympathize with a libertarian argument against coercively confiscating rescurces and funneling them into the hands of others doesn't mean the entire argument is invalid.
At the minimum, then, we can agree that Fed OMOs are no different than gov't salaries or gov't subsidies.
Posted by: RPLong | December 05, 2012 at 01:45 PM
RPLong:
Again, only inasmuch as the FBI is a toilet paper subsidy. The money going to banks is a minor operating cost of the Fed, and minuscule relative to actual things the Fed does. It is macroeconomically irrelevant.
Posted by: Alex Godofsky | December 05, 2012 at 01:52 PM
K,
"c) controlling the nominal short rate also means controlling the real short rate because inflation expectations move in the opposite direction of the nominal short rate (this last bit is at the core of what's so horribly wrong with the entire RBC literature)."
No, controlling the nominal short rate does not mean controlling the real short rate. Inflation expectations are only part of the story (they can affect liquidity preference). You are forgetting about credit (new money) demand and productivity.
This is a chicken and egg problem. The real short term interest rate is determined after the money is borrowed not before. If new borrowing increases the demand for goods more than the supply of goods then prices as measured in that money will rise. If new borrowing increases the supply of goods more than the demand for goods, then prices as measured in that money will fall. The price change happens after the money is borrowed.
If a consumer borrows money on his credit card to buy some good, then the immediate effect on prices is an increase in demand over the current supply - real interest rate falls. Likewise if a producer borrows money to fund the production of some good (pays employees), then the immediate effect on prices is an increase in supply over the current demand - real interest rate rises.
Cantillion effects can be liquidity preference issues that happen after newly borrowed money is spent.
Posted by: Frank Restly | December 05, 2012 at 01:59 PM
Thanks Nick. One more from me please. (And I'm not asking these to trap you, I'm asking so I fairly recapitulate what your position is.) If the Fed were to suddenly dump its mortgage-backed securities and replace them with gold, would that have any impact on the real estate and mortgage industries, and the world price of gold, relative to the counterfactual? Again, list any caveats you need.
Posted by: Bob Murphy | December 05, 2012 at 02:02 PM
Frank, goods prices (particularly retail) are sticky - fixed, even - over time scales in which asset prices are fully flexible.
Posted by: Alex Godofsky | December 05, 2012 at 02:07 PM
Alex, I thought we understood that I was not talking about macroeconomic relevance, but rather microeconomic relevance? So long as we agree that OMOs are conferring on specific individuals profits that they would not otherwise receive in absence of the existence of central banks, then we agree on every claim those crazy Austrians are making.
I agree with you and Sumner that the overall impact of these benefits is negligible with respect to the money supply and NGDP growth. So, too, would it be macroeconomically irrelevant if my personal salary quadrupled tomorrow. But no one would suggest that I am personally no better off in light of that quadrupling's negligible impact on the macroeconomy.
I think we've reached a good meeting of the minds here, though. You now have all the information you need to see that the Austrian claims in this case are microeconomically significant; the Austrians likewise have all the information they need to understand that those same gains are macroeconomically irrelevant.
So we've cleared the debate up now, despite its requiring some five major economics blogs to do it. :)
Posted by: RPLong | December 05, 2012 at 02:20 PM
Nick,
Is the key dispute here is over market competition?
I think you're saying that competition squashes the Cantillon effects into a wealth subsidy. Sort of: "I know the Fed is buying stuff, but you guys could *all* sell that stuff to the Fed. Or buy up that stuff and *resell* it to the Fed." If everyone knew that the Fed was going to buy up GM stock or bananas, then the producers and current holders of GM stock and bananas would adjust their prices higher (or the prices would be higher at equilibrium, whatever). The producers and holders get subsidized. Everyone else pays in real terms. But there's no "price ripple" from the *final sellers to the Fed* and everyone else.
I think the wealth transfer argument is weaker for markets where producer entry is easy (and capital goods are not very specific?). If you see the Fed making the banana producers wealthier, then I'd like to also be a banana producer.
Also, if the Fed buys up stuff with a monopoly producer (say US government bonds), then only the producer (and those who hold this stuff when the policy is announced?) get subsidized. For government bonds, this "subsidy" is basically seniorage.
Posted by: marris | December 05, 2012 at 02:23 PM
RPLong
No, because
1) The Austrian critique is not that the banks earning a few tens of millions in fees or whatever is this horrible distorting thing.
2) I'll go one further and say it has no "economic" relevance at all. It is an incredible waste of time to even be talking about it. The "economic" distortion is, again, equivalent to the distortion caused by the government buying paper. No one talks about government purchase of office supplies as economic policy, no one cares about it at all.
Yes, your argument on this point has wasted space across many blogs. Are you proud that you've proven to everyone that the government - gasp - has to actually spend money on basic administration?
Note that the actual Austrians here (e.g. Bob) never talk about this stuff because they know it's inane and irrelevant.
Posted by: Alex Godofsky | December 05, 2012 at 02:27 PM
Frank,
r = i - pi, plain and simple.
The CB controls i. pi does *not* go up if the CB surprise-raises i (if anything, it goes down a bit). Therefore r goes up by *at least* as much as i. Therefore the CB has powerful control over r (ignoring the ZLB).
Posted by: K | December 05, 2012 at 02:28 PM
This is a very nice demonstration, Nick. Here I recommend how you can apply the same technique to another contentious issue. (I am trying a link in here; if it doesn't work I will paste in the URL.)
Posted by: Gene Callahan | December 05, 2012 at 02:28 PM
Alex, did I miss something? Did I insult you (or anyone!) and not realize it? I posed a question I hoped Nick Rowe would answer - nobody begged you to engage me in any kind of discussion or debate. I am sorry that your need to respond to me resulted in a waste of your time. I am also sorry if I accidentally insulted you.
Posted by: RPLong | December 05, 2012 at 02:32 PM
ssumner:
Nick, I of course agree that fiscal differences matter. I was discussing the Austrian view that if the central bank buys injects money by buying bonds, it depends who they buy them from. But fiscal policy is the same whether the bonds are purchased from person A or person B. I assume you agree with that. Appearently some Austrians don't.
That wasn't the initial dispute. You're changing the subject. Austrians are not arguing that "fiscal policy" per se has to change if bonds are bought from A rather than B. They are saying that the Cantillon Effects take place when the Fed buys bonds, the same way it takes place when the Fed buys cars or gold.
Call it "monetary, not fiscal policy" if you want, but the Fed is doing it in the bond market.
Posted by: Major_Freedom | December 05, 2012 at 02:48 PM
Nick Rowe:
Bob Murphy asked:
In normal times (not when we're up against ZLB), if the Fed decides to cut short-term interest rates and buys Treasuries, do you agree that this really does push down short-term interest rates (raise price of short-term safe bonds)? You can give whatever caveats you want, but I want to understand what power you think the central bank has over the market price of bonds, if any.
And you responded with:
Bob: Long run (flexible prices): if a central bank permanently loosens monetary policy by raising the inflation target (increasing the money growth rate), nominal bond prices will fall.
Short run (sticky prices): if the central bank temporarily loosens monetary policy, but leaves the long run target unchanged, nominal bond prices may rise.
If the Fed decides to lower interest rates, so that they can do what you call "boosting the economy", and you believe that permanent inflation will not be able to keep rates low, and will raise rates in the long run, due to price inflation, then does that not mean that if the Fed wants to KEEP interest rates low (say for slightly more than "the long run", and this can be longer than 1 year or 1.5 years or whatever), that the Fed has to increase the rate of monetary inflation, repeatedly, so that it can always exploit "sticky prices" so as to keep rates low and avoid the price inflation effects pushing interest rates back up?
Posted by: Major_Freedom | December 05, 2012 at 02:54 PM
Nick, I call your attention to Gene Callahan's post above. You really need to read that please, when you get time. He has Mate in 3 moves.
Posted by: Bob Murphy | December 05, 2012 at 02:58 PM
"We can consolidate the government's and central bank's balance sheets"
Yow. Income statements too, by necessity? Going all MMT on us here. And: Where's JKH when we need him? (http://monetaryrealism.com/treasury-and-the-central-bank-a-contingent-institutional-approach/)
"by the same account you have to be outraged that those very same bond dealers gather undue profits from regular yearly government deficits an order of magnitude higher."
And I am. Just because people want or "demand" >0% nominal returns on perfectly safe assets doesn't mean that the government is obligated to provide them. They could just be printing dollar bills instead of T-bills, and using some other vehicle to set the floor on interest rates.
IOR comes to mind, though of course that is also a "gift" to banks... Looking forward to JKH's upcoming on the old "Chicago Plan" for full reserve banking.
Posted by: Steve Roth | December 05, 2012 at 03:18 PM
Save your fingers, Nick.
While the controversy about public works was developing, Professor Robbins sent to Vienna for a member of the Austrian school to provide a counter attraction to Keynes. I very well remember Hayek's visit to Cambridge on his way to the London School. He expounded his theory and covered a black board with his triangles. The whole argument, as we could see later, consisted in confusing the current rate of investment with the total stock of capital goods, but we could not make it out at the time. The general tendency seemed to be to show that the slump was caused by [excessive] consumption. R. F. Kahn, who was at that time involved in explaining that the multiplier guaranteed that saving equals investment, asked in a puzzled tone, "Is it your view that if I went out tomorrow and bought a new overcoat, that would increase unemployment?"' "Yes," said Hayek, "but," pointing to his triangles on the board, "it would take a very long mathematical argument to explain why."
This pitiful state of confusion was the first crisis of economic theory that I referred to...
St. Hayek was just plain wrong.
Posted by: Determinant | December 05, 2012 at 04:29 PM
Attributed to the august Joan Robinson.
Posted by: Determinant | December 05, 2012 at 04:30 PM
K,
"r = i - pi, plain and simple. The CB controls i. pi does *not* go up if the CB surprise-raises i (if anything, it goes down a bit). Therefore r goes up by *at least* as much as i. Therefore the CB has powerful control over r (ignoring the ZLB). "
The CB can set the nominal interest rate above or below the rate of inflation, this is true (limited by the ZLB). But that measure of the rate of inflation is based upon previous price changes. If the CB sets the nominal interest rate at some level and no one is willing to borrow at that rate, then has the CB set the "real" interest rate?
Step #1: Central bank sets nominal interest rate at some level
Step #2: Individual / Company / Government borrows money at that rate and spends the money
Step #3: Depending on how that money is spent prices could rise or they could fall
Posted by: Frank Restly | December 05, 2012 at 05:40 PM
Only a Keynesian could conflate a decrease in government expropriation with a "transfer increase." That is much like saying if a man is holding another man's head under water and decides to stop holding him under water, he has increased him.
It's also like mobsters deciding not to collect protection money one week and treating the money they have not stolen as an "increase" to those who were left in peace.
...very, *very* odd logic.
Posted by: K. Alan Bates | December 05, 2012 at 06:03 PM
(I didn't finish that thought...which is *why* it is very odd logic for a non-Keynesian to use)
Posted by: K. Alan Bates | December 05, 2012 at 06:08 PM
I start by seeing this:
Scott Sumner and Bill Woolsey have been fighting valiantly against the Austrians. The fight is about "Cantillon effects" -- non-neutralities of money that are supposed to arise not from the increase in the money supply itself but from where exactly that new money enters the economy.
I think, oh, you mean like different fiscal multipliers? And then end up reading this:
Sorry. What was the question again? Was it: "Do Cantillon effects matter?" Or was it "Does fiscal policy matter?" I can't tell the difference. There is no difference. "Cantillon effects" are just another name for "the effects of fiscal policy".
*Pats self on back*
Although the name sounds familiar, I can't recall "Cantillon effects" being discussed in any other context, or in any of my textbooks. Romer's Macro is right here, and that's not in it.
Are the Austrians basically like Marxists - with their own vocabulary, frequently just to describe very mundane phenomena?
Posted by: Edmund | December 05, 2012 at 07:58 PM
I can't recall "Cantillon effects" being discussed in any other context, or in any of my textbooks. Romer's Macro is right here, and that's not in it.
Must not be important then.
Posted by: Bob Murphy | December 05, 2012 at 08:57 PM
Frank:
Measured inflation is based upon previous price changes. Current inflation (alternately: expected inflation) is an instantaneous thing that exists and has some value even if we can only measure it ex post.
Posted by: Alex Godofsky | December 05, 2012 at 09:18 PM
Must not be important then.
You get ten internet points for snark - but actually, yeah, important macroeconomic concepts usually show up in recent macroeconomic textbooks.
The Austrians love the market. In the market for ideas, Austrian economics hasn't done well. Should this not give one pause?
Posted by: Edmund | December 05, 2012 at 09:18 PM
There is definitely a stocks vs flows issue here. If you ignore the stocks aspect--all exchanges are of new production, I think you will get a different answer.
The OMO is income to someone. Now suppose P > MC. So the seller is not merely transferring assets at cost. it isn't an exchange of like for like. So, there is a profit. Now, we have utility from the transaction. This person then exchanges the income for goods and the seller profits, and again there is utility.
When the Fed buys treasuries, these first around effects accrue to the monopolist who manufacturers treasuries: the treasury.
Posted by: Jon | December 05, 2012 at 10:54 PM
Proper name for them: Falscher Osterreichischer Sturmtruppen.
Posted by: Edmund | December 05, 2012 at 10:57 PM
Alex,
"Current inflation (alternately: expected inflation) is an instantaneous thing that exists and has some value even if we can only measure it ex post."
For the federal reserve to set or have any control over the real interest rate they must have foresight of what future inflation will be. Sure inflation expectations and their affect on liquidity preference shape future realized inflation but those are not the only factors.
The central bank could expect 5% inflation and only get 1%. If a central bank sets the nominal interest rate to 8%, expects 5% inflation, and gets 1% inflation, what is the real interest rate that was set by the bank - 8% nominal - 5% expected = 3% real or 8% nominal - 1% realized = 7% real?
Credit demand and productivity also shape what future inflation will be.
Posted by: Frank Restly | December 06, 2012 at 04:32 AM
Yes, if they want to fine-tune the real interest rate they would need that. But since inflation expectations and nominal interest rates tend to move in opposite directions (in the short term), the central bank can be reasonably sure that a cut in nominal interest rates will cause a cut in real interest rates, even if they aren't sure of the precise magnitude.
(Also, they can get a pretty good measure of inflation expectations right after the cut by looking at TIPS spreads.)
Posted by: Alex Godofsky | December 06, 2012 at 05:56 AM
Alex,
"Also, they can get a pretty good measure of inflation expectations right after the cut by looking at TIPS spreads."
TIPs spreads presume the existence of TIPS. They are a relatively new invention (first introduced in the US by Bob Rubin in 1997). TIPs are a form of debt that pays a fixed interest rate plus a measure of previously incurred inflation. Ultimately the value of TIPs is influenced by previously incurred inflation AND the supply and demand for TIPs.
Suppose the federal government decides to run a budget surplus and reduce the quantity of TIPs in circulation relative to the quantity of nominal bonds in circulation. The spread between TIPs and nominal bonds closes - but not because of a change in inflation expectations.
1. How does the central bank separate supply / demand changes in TIPs & nominal bonds versus changes in inflation expectations?
2. Ultimately inflation expectations are one way to look at changes in liquidity preference, but the two can move in opposite directions. Inflation expectations can rise while liquidity preference also rises. People can expect higher prices (war induced supply shortage) while still having a high liquidity preference (recession induced loss of permanent income).
"The central bank can be reasonably sure that a cut in nominal interest rates will cause a cut in real interest rates, even if they aren't sure of the precise magnitude."
If that were the case then the deflation of the Great Depression could never have happened.
Posted by: Frank Restly | December 06, 2012 at 06:37 AM
Alex,
[ INT * ( 1 - LP ) / LP + f'(t) / LP ] / ( 1 + IR ) = PROD
IR = [ ( INT * ( 1 - LP ) / LP + f'(t) / LP ) / PROD ] - 1
Inflation Rate = [ ( Nominal Interest Rate * ( 1 - Liquidity Preference ) / Liquidity Preference + Change in Credit Demand with Respect to Time ) / Productivity ] - 1
INT - Nominal interest rate is set by Federal Reserve
f(t) - Change in credit demand with respect to time is set by combination of market and government
LP - Liquidity preference is set by combination of market and government (liquidity preference of government is 0)
PROD - Productivity is determined by market
If the change in credit demand with respect to time is sufficiently negative, then the inflation rate will go negative irrespective of the nominal interest rate.
Posted by: Frank Restly | December 06, 2012 at 07:01 AM
Frank:
Well then it's a good thing that they really do exist, don'tcha think? ;)
Possibly (probably?) not. It depends on three things:
1) The demand for inflation hedges.
2) The supply of inflation hedges (including but not limited to TIPS).
3) The supply of TIPS (only at the extreme end; if TIPS are sufficiently rare then the market in them will be illiquid).
Basically, so long as the demand for inflation hedges doesn't so far outstrip the supply as to make them unsubstitutable with other financial assets, the TIPS spread should be a pretty decent measure of inflation expectations.
Regarding all the equations, I don't see how you are improving on the simple model of:
[Expected] Real Interest Rate = Nominal Interest Rate - [Expected] Inflation
combined with "If I, Ben Bernanke, announce a nominal interest rate cut, ceteris paribus expected inflation will probably go up,"
to get "therefore reducing the nominal interest rate will also reduce real interest rates".
Posted by: Alex Godofsky | December 06, 2012 at 08:55 AM
Alex,
Regarding all the equations, I don't see how you are improving on the simple model of:
[Expected] Real Interest Rate = Nominal Interest Rate - [Expected] Inflation combined with "If I, Ben Bernanke, announce a nominal interest rate cut, ceteris paribus expected inflation will probably go up," to get "therefore reducing the nominal interest rate will also reduce real interest rates".
The simple model of interest rates does not include
1. Someone must borrow at those rates for them to have any economic effect ( credit demand = f(t) )
2. Someone who borrows the money must spend the money for it to have an economic effect ( liquidity preference = LP )
3. How the money is spent will determine in part what the economic effect of the money is ( productivity = PROD )
IR = [ ( INT * ( 1 - LP ) / LP + f'(t) / LP ) / PROD ] - 1
Realized inflation does not depend on inflation expectations but instead on liquidity preference, productivity, nominal interest rate, and credit demand.
Hasn't economics evolved beyond confidence fairies, inflation expectations, and pink unicorns?
Posted by: Frank Restly | December 06, 2012 at 09:55 AM
Alex,
Snipe hunt much?
Posted by: K | December 06, 2012 at 10:00 AM
Re: my previous, I see that JW Mason has a new post coming at this the same way, about the IMF's reincarnation of the Chicago Plan:
"If government liabilities are more liquid than the liabilities of even the biggest banks, as they certainly seem to be, then the banking system plays no function with respect to federal borrowing. The banks that hold federal debt are providing "anti-intermediation" -- they are replacing more liquid assets with less liquid ones. In this sense, whatever income banks get from holding federal debt and providing means of payment are pure rents - it would be more efficient for federal liabilities to serve as means of payment directly."
Or as I said, issue dollat bills instead of t bills.
"The goal of the plan is to, in effect, collapse the categories of inside money, outside money and government debt by eliminating the first and turning the third into the second. Equivalently, it's an attempt to legislate the economy into functioning the way monetarists (and some MMTers) say it already does"
The way it's depicted here, no?
Posted by: Steve Roth | December 06, 2012 at 10:48 AM
Edmund: Austrians are indeed like Marxists. Something about central european water?
Loser in the market for ideas? They should heed Chris Dillow moto "An extremist not a fanatic" but like all true believer the smaller the number of followers, the truer they are to the faith.
BTW, my german being rusty I tried Babelfish
in french: Incorrects Beauceron storm troopers
in english: Incorrect Beauceron storm troopers
in italian :Errata Beauceron storm troopers
Canadian readers ,and Québécois especially, will appreciate. We know Beaucerons have a reputation for hardy entrepreneurship but at that level...?
Googletranslate got it but it isn't as fun... so I might get into a Google
automatic car but probably not in a Yahoo one...
BAck to grading
Posted by: Jacques René Giguère | December 06, 2012 at 10:55 AM
Frank:
Posted by: Alex Godofsky | December 06, 2012 at 11:00 AM
Steve Roth:
Bank liabilities (i.e. deposits) are far more liquid than T-Bills, reserves, or even currency. I can use my debit card at the store; I can't use T-Bills or reserves, and currency is inconvenient to carry around.
Posted by: Alex Godofsky | December 06, 2012 at 11:03 AM
Alex,
None of the above. That is why I went through the process in my head and on paper on how realized inflation can be calculated. Obviously this calculation is way oversimplified. It does not include equity financing, it does not include fiscal policy effects (taxes, government spending, etc.), it does not included default premiums in private credit (AAA, BBB, junk debt), it does not include trade balance and currency effects, and it does not include a few other things that I am missing.
What I was trying to do was isolate the independent variables of choice (credit demand, liquidity preference, nominal interest rate, productivity) from a result (inflation or lack of inflation). Inflation / deflation is a result of economic choices, it is not an original input. Of course past changes in inflation can affect future choices (feed back effects), but those need to be modeled as such.
Posted by: Frank Restly | December 06, 2012 at 11:22 AM
Frank:
OK, so I went back and looked at your equation. Let's take the partial wrt INT, howabout?
IR = [ ( INT * ( 1 - LP ) / LP + f'(t) / LP ) / PROD ] - 1
dIR = (dINT*(1-LP)/LP)/PROD
LP and PROD are supposed to be positive numbers, right? Thus sign(dIR) = sign(dINT), so you think we live in world 3. This should give you pause, because AFAIK pretty much no one else believes this and it is opposite the usual intuition.
Posted by: Alex Godofsky | December 06, 2012 at 11:45 AM
Alex,
IR = [ ( INT * ( 1 - LP ) / LP + f'(t) / LP ) / PROD ] - 1
dIR/dt = dINT/dt * ( 1 - LP) / ( LP * PROD ) + f''(t) / ( LP * PROD )
You forgot that credit demand ( f(t) ) is a function of time as well. And so sign( dIR/dt ) may not equal sign ( dINT/dt ).
Posted by: Frank Restly | December 06, 2012 at 11:58 AM
I said partial derivative with respect to the nominal interest rate. There's no dt.
Posted by: Alex Godofsky | December 06, 2012 at 12:07 PM
Alex,
Sorry. I misunderstood your terminology.
dIR/dINT = ( 1 - LP ) / ( LP * PROD )
Assuming that credit demand, liquidity preference, and productivity are constants - yes lowering nominal interest rates will lower the inflation rate. That is a lot of assumptions.
Posted by: Frank Restly | December 06, 2012 at 12:56 PM
Jacques,
I was going for "false Austrian storm troopers" with what little German I know.
Posted by: Edmund | December 06, 2012 at 02:00 PM
Assuming that credit demand, liquidity preference, and productivity are constants - yes lowering nominal interest rates will lower the inflation rate. That is a lot of assumptions.
Understated.
Posted by: Edmund | December 06, 2012 at 02:01 PM
Frank: "Assuming that credit demand, liquidity preference, and productivity are constants - yes lowering nominal interest rates will lower the inflation rate."
Oh Christ
Posted by: Nick Rowe | December 06, 2012 at 02:19 PM