« A preliminary estimate for Canadian 2010Q2 GDP growth | Main | What were they thinking? One view »

Comments

Feed You can follow this conversation by subscribing to the comment feed for this post.

It seems to me that for the "supply is relatively more elastic than demand" case, where the seller can pass the tax on to the consumer, the seller could have simply raised the price instead of waiting for the tax to be installed.

This should even work when there is (so-called) competition.

So I think your analysis for this case may not be complete: the price before the tax already incorporates the possibility of the tax.

When I was a young man in Japan, the gov't increased the tax on alcoholic beverages sold by the drink. Immediately the bars and restaurants increased the prices of those drinks by around three times the tax increase. ;)


I think that, as usual, the theoretical analysis contains a number of hidden assumptions. The most obvious one is that the payer of the tax is able to pass on the tax to consumers where elasticity of supply permits. There can be all sorts of constraints on this, ranging from risk of social or regulatory retaliation to ability to offset in other areas to various forms of corporatism. Before I bought the analysis (which suggests that all taxes on the rich will end up on the poor), I would like to see the results of extended case studies over time, taking into account other changes.

Does it follow that if the incidence of corporate taxes falls on workers, then reducing corporate taxes will cause the wages of workers to rise? If so, then have the significant corporate tax reductions in Canada over the past decade shown up in the wages paid to workers? How have they shown up, empirically?

"Before I bought the analysis (which suggests that all taxes on the rich will end up on the poor)"

Keep in mind this isn't what Prof. Gordon is showing - just the incidence of *some* taxes (and to be fair, the incidence isn't being placed on 'the poor', rather it's being placed on 'labour').

Anyhow, a terrific post. I've been meaning to do something like this for awhile.

Which graphs apply to Canada's banks, and the oil sands industry?

Do big sector fish in a small economic pond make the empirical evidence for small open economies is pretty less entirely clear?

Not an economist, but the post is clear enough. That said, pricing power comes from a wide array of circumstances that, in my opinion, may not be that susceptible to supply and demand.

Right now we have a decided lack of overall demand. So it would follow that in many cases pricing power is compromised. Yet corporate profits are at historic highs matched by historic highs in cash on hand. Someone obviously still retains a reasonable amount of pricing power.

Corporations cut supply, and employment, to match the reduced demand. Yet the profit figures indicate pricing was maintained. My questions is, what other factors might be influencing the pricing power maintenance?

How does the analysis of tax incidence, when the tax in question is a land value tax? The influential Martin Wolf is agitating for land taxes.

Here's what one campaign website* has to say:

IMPOSSIBLE TO PASS ON IN HIGHER PRICES, LOWER WAGES OR HIGHER RENTS. Competition makes it impossible for a business producing goods on a valuable site to charge more per item than one producing similar goods on less valuable land - after all, producers and traders at different locations are paying different rents to landlords now, yet like goods generally sell for much the same price and employers pay their workers comparable wages. The tax cannot be passed on to a tenant who is already paying the full market rent.

what do you make of that?

* the economic literacy of which I can't vouch for

Luis Enrique, land taxes are capitalized in the value of land, so yes they are simply paid by existing landowners. But the main selling point of the land tax is that if implemented correctly it does not distort economic activity like other forms of taxation do, so a LVT which was implemented as a tax shift might even _increase_ asset values by removing the excess burden which currently falls on real estate.

Incidentally, this reveals a gap in Gordon's reasoning about corporate taxation. Even in a small open economy, some of the incidence of corporate taxes might be capitalized in the value of firm-specific assets (including but not limited to commercial real estate). The tax would effectively fall on existing stockholders, but the elasticity of capital supply would be irrelevant.

Stephen - I wonder if there's a different way of labelling your figures that clarifies the differences between them.

The ones on the left hand side are showing things from the demander's point of view: their demand curve hasn't changed, but suddenly firms are charging them more for any given amount they want to buy. Another way of saying this: in the left hand side graphs, the place where the supply and demand curve cross is the *before tax* (e.g. including HST) price.

The ones of the right hand side show things from the suppliers point of view: their before-tax cost structure hasn't changed, and the price they need to receive after tax to make it worthwhile supplying goods hasn't changed, but suddenly, because of the tax, people aren't willing to pay as high an after-tax price for their goods. So on the right hand side graphs, the intersection of supply and demand is the *after tax* price.

I find the idea of a selling price confusing - when I buy something, the receipt shows a before-tax price, an amount of tax, and an after-tax total. So what's the selling price? How many people actually know what the legal statutory incidence of HST or CPP premiums etc is anyways?

thanks anon - sorry to be dim, but what does "land taxes are capitalized in the value of land" mean?

(I'm using to thinking "capitalized" is to do with accounting treatment of capital expenditure - amortization in P&L - I can't figure how that relates to land taxes)

Frances - I was trying to come up with a way of distinguishing between the case where the tax is on one side and on the other. The idea behind the graph is that if the purchaser pays, she does so on her way out of the store at some sort of tax kiosk. Probably not the best choice.

Luis Enrique, the value of land is generally understood in economics as the net present value of the stream of all future rents (or the unobserved equivalent of "rents" if the real estate is not rented out). A land value tax is effectively a tax on future rents, so the sale price of land is lowered accordingly.

This is actually a significant problem with land value taxation: its incidence is felt immediately in lower asset values for landowners (leading to lower apparent wealth), but the benefits occur over time and are far less concentrated. This means that land taxes have to be implemented gradually and as a tax shift from distortionary forms of taxation, otherwise they are politically indistinguishable from a simple taking or confiscation of property.

thanks v much anon.

I'm not sure I understand why landlords would not increase rents upon the announcement of an LVT. If they tried to, the gradient between rents in high and low LVT areas would increase, so you'd predict some (but not all) tenants to move. So I wouldn't expect landlords to be able to pass on the whole LVT in higher rents, but why not some? Also, if tenant did move to low LVT areas, that'd increase value of land in these areas.

Luis Enrique, I'm not sure what your point is, but it is assumed that landowners are charging as much rent as the market will bear, both in high- and low-LVT areas. This makes sense because (1) due to competition, no single landowner can charge more than what the market will bear. (2) land does not have a "cost of production" which equates to the rent being paid: its supply is entirely inelastic.

My point is to doubt the argument that because landowners are charging as much rent as the market will bear they cannot partially pass on LVT. Rather than think about single landowners, think about all landowners making a simultaneous price change. The announcement of an LVT sounds like a good coordinating device to me. Put it this way, if an LVT was announced, how much would you bet on zero impact on rents?

"Rather than think about single landowners, think about all landowners making a simultaneous price change."

You're assuming that landowners can collude to raise rents above the market price and keep land out of use. It may be true that the announcement of a LVT is a feasible coordination device, but collusion would break down in the long run (disregarding special cases such as LVT being higher than the available rent, which would result in the abandonment of property rights by landowners) Generally speaking, LVT tends to encourage effective land use compared to no tax.

A mixed bag, but worth a read ...

http://economix.blogs.nytimes.com/2010/07/23/who-ultimately-pays-the-corporate-income-tax/

All that being said, I agree with Krugman in that Fisher's recent speech *is* depressing. It's one thing to make a mistake (IMO a justifiable one), but it's another thing not to learn from it.

I think Irwin Gillespie got this one right when he argued that owners pay corporate income tax up to some global (or in Canada's case, US) tax rate, and any excess is shifted to consumers or workers. So as an overall policy issue, with Canada's corporate tax rates lower than in the US, there is no reason to believe that CIT gets shifted to workers.

Even if you don't buy that, there are likely to be some differences across industries: some industries are regulated in terms of price or actual rate of return; most service industries are not really mobile in the sense that they need to have market presence in order to make any money; and others need access to resources -- in the case of tar sands there are very few places companies can invest money.

So really this is about a handful of industries, mostly in manufacturing, where the open economy metaphor is appropriate. But note that well before recent CIT cuts, Canada had a lower rate for manufacturing and processing, as compared to service industries.

My default would thus be to assume that CIT is paid by owners and is thus is a progressive tax.

Reference?

The second and third paragraphs are wrong. The argument is based on the openness of capital markets.

Disagree. Ultimately, this issue depends on how one views how companies make investment decisions. That is, they invest based on the hope they will make lots of money, above and beyond their costs, but overall this is a highly uncertain process. If they make money, they pay tax on it. Along the way they try to minimize their labour costs, and charge as much as they can for the good or service being produced. End of story.

That's why you can only cite a handful of flawed empirical studies to back your case.

For the Gillespie reference, you'll be pleased to know that when I googled it, I came up with a WCI blog post!
http://worthwhile.typepad.com/worthwhile_canadian_initi/2006/08/canada_already_.html

No, the issue is where the savings comes from to finance those investment decisions.

And in the reference, Gillespie and his co-author *assume* that the CIT is borne by owners of capital. It's not a result derived from a set of explicitly-stated assumptions or supported by data.

It seems to me Marc is questioning the assumptions - not the theory. I agree with the points he raises.


Intuitively, I'd agree that payroll taxes are shifted to labour as companies look at their total wage bill inclusive of payroll tax. I'd also argue that carbon taxes or sales taxes on inputs are shifted to consumers as these are a cost of doing business. And business price as a mark-up over average costs.

It is just the CIT shifting that I have some quibbles with. I don't think Stephen has made a compelling counter-argument to the intuition Gillespie brought to this many decades ago, especially in the Canadian case.

Here's a contrary bit of data that disproves Stephen's whole point: over the past decade we have seen major corporate tax cuts, but at the same time a rising profit share (and decreasing wage share) of GDP. In Stephen's theory, CIT cuts should be passed on to workers. But no. Why? Corporations try to make as much money as they can.

Open capital markets? Capital is what capital does: invest in order to make a profit, on which they then pay CIT. Like I said, it is a simple story and economists do a dis-service when they create complicated stories like marginal effective tax rates and shifting of CIT onto labour.

By the way, I did a Canadian tax incidence study that follows Gillespie and updates tax incidence up to 2005:
http://www.policyalternatives.ca/publications/commentary/putting-fairness-back-canada%E2%80%99s-tax-system

Here's a contrary bit of data that disproves Stephen's whole point: over the past decade we have seen major corporate tax cuts, but at the same time a rising profit share (and decreasing wage share) of GDP.

The theory doesn't say anything about income shares, even conditioning on everything else. Wages should increase, but so should investment and the capital stock. The net effect on income shares is indeterminate.

The comments to this entry are closed.

Search this site

  • Google

    WWW
    worthwhile.typepad.com
Blog powered by Typepad