« Some reasons not to take an undergraduate degree in economics | Main | Taylor = Wicksell + Fisher + Friedman »

Comments

Feed You can follow this conversation by subscribing to the comment feed for this post.

Some of my colleagues went through a similar exercise for Quebec, including the effects of transfers; I blogged about it here (OMG - 4 years ago!!).

They got a similar story, only the effect of withdrawing transfers as income increases makes the effective marginal tax rates much higher. There's even an interval where they exceed 100%.

Mike, your analysis of the CPP is fundamentally flawed. CPP bears little relation in its current form to US Social Security to the point that comparisons are irrelevant.

CPP and QPP are currently identical in form and implementation: a universal defined-benefit pension plan supported by investment returns. Both CPP and QPP funds are invested in external financial instruments (often out of Canada). They are not solely invested in Government bonds and therefore do not depend on the government's credit and tax guarantee. In this it is unlike Social Security.

With defined-benefit pensions it is customary to carve out both contributions and benefits and let the DB RPP "wrap-around" CPP. Benefits from CPP are tied directly to contributions. Universal social welfare payments to seniors are delivered through Old-Age Security and Guaranteed Income Supplement. Both are funded out of the Consolidated Revenue Fund, that is through tax revenue, just like any other welfare problem. CPP provides benefits to contributors, period. Canada is different from the US in that old-age welfare comes explicitly out of general tax revenues.

The insurance redistribution provided through CPP is the same as that provided through any other defined-benefit pension plan, aka life annuity.

Second, marketing material from life insurance companies is biased. I have worked in that industry. Never forget that they are salespeople, ever. Such material is intended to motivate people to save more in insurance company products. The truth of such material is open to debate however it is not and will never be unbiased research.

Stephen: I recall reading a mid 1980s study that suggested that a single mom living in subsidized housing with 3 kids faced a marginal tax rate around 120-130%.

Determinant: Agreed on the differences between CPP and SS. However, I think you missed the major point: "if young workers believe they will receive no personal benefits from their contributions, then the behavioural response is the same as an income tax."

Whether CPP is stable or a complete mess is largely irrelevant - it's the belief that drives behaviour.

That being said, I wish there was better behavioral research on whether people see (and act as if) CPP contributions and income taxes as being identical. I suspect for my age bracket they do, but there really isn't much evidence either way.

RE: "Second, marketing material from life insurance companies is biased. I have worked in that industry. Never forget that they are salespeople, ever."

That was exactly my point.

Now, it would be true that looking at the U.S. situation is misleading if the *beliefs* of Canadians differed significantly from that of Americans. I can't say for certain either way - I can't find much of anything on Canadian beliefs RE: CPP (let alone on behavioural responses), which is why I discussed the U.S. situation. I'll continue looking and update that section if I find anything good.

Employee paid CPP and EI contributions and premiums are non-refundable tax credits. Have a closer look at Schedule 1 of a T1. Please rework your tax brackets.

Whoops - good eye! I do have to re-do the math here somewhat. Don't think it will change the results appreciably, but I do want to be as accurate as possible.

We typically analyze the redistribution in a tax system according to average, not marginal tax rates. You are right that the Canadian tax system does not feature monotonic marginal tax rates. But this doesn't directly have welfare implications. If you want to talk about regressivity/progressivity of the whole system, you ought to use average burdens. Marginal tax rates only matter insofar as they affect average burdens.

Don't think it will change the results appreciably

Agreed. There is a kink in the lower part of the second T1 tax bracket if federal income taxes and CPP contributions and EI premiums (payroll) are commingled with or without a percentage of the employer share of payroll being allocated to the employee.

Any employee benefits arising from the commingling are not kinked, however.

Mike:

Your point is not accurate. What American workers believe and what Canadian workers believe are two independent things and cannot be assumed to be correlated. The comparison you attempted is a straw-man argument. Different nations, different policies, different implementations.

In your analysis, you would have to treat a private defined-benefit RPP as a tax. The arguments you attempt to levy are the same as for a DB RPP, except for the sponsor. In this case sponsor solvency risk is significantly less with CPP. The redistribution/cross-subsidization is the same. In fact the only two differences with CPP are the fact that the pool of contributors includes all working Canadians, the manager is the Government of Canada and premiums are collected through the tax system.

You have also not addressed the fact that wealth redistribution in Canada is conducted through the policy instrument of OAS/GIS, not CPP. The benefits provided under OAS are funded through current tax revenue and are means tested. Neither is true for CPP.

Third, it's financially impossible in Canada (not to mention malpractice) to ignore the effects of CPP in financial planning, both income and benefits. If you do it yourself and most especially if you have an employer or counsellor do it for you, you have to take CPP into account. Just because people gripe about the future doesn't mean they don't take present legal realities into account when planning. There is a fundamental difference between what they say and what they do. I've been there.

Put a graph up at http://twitpic.com/2jgkeh.

As always it would be nice to see the evolution of the figures over the last decades

-- Stephan

Hi Kevin,

You read my mind - planning on following up with analysis of avg. rates, though I do believe marg. Rates have welfare implications beyond avg. Rates.

When I get back to office will fix tax credit issue and do avg. Rates in a couple of days.

Mike: If I have 100K income, my welfare changes if I pay 20K or 40K taxes on that 100K. This is the average tax burden. if I pay 99% or 1% on hypothetical dollar #100,001, it does not change my current welfare given that I am at $100K.

Marginal tax rates matter a lot for efficiency. They also matter because for equity because they affect average tax rates. But on their own they do not affect equity.

Agreed. I need to clarify my thinking here - it's one of those things that made sense to me at 6am.

CPP is not a tax. It is retirement pension. 100% forced savings, if you want to put it that way. But we all benefit from the resulting automatic stabilization.

EI is not a tax. It is an insurance plan. While not all individuals will collect that insurance, everyone benefits from the automatic stabilization during recessions.

These positive effects function whether or not individuals believe in them.

Attempts to lump these two into the "taxation" category smell of hard core free market ideology. And we have seen where that kind of thinking has gotten us in the last few years.

Mike: While I digest this, one typo:

"CPP Employer Contribution Rates

* 0%: $0 - $3500
* 4.95%: $3501 - $47,200"

Should be EmployeE, I think?

Whoops - thanks Nick - fixed now!

Thanks everyone for your comments - I'm going to revamp this tomorrow to clarify a few areas; was going to tonight, but just got back from a 2 year old's birthday party and am absolutely wrecked. Kids are exhausting.

In short: The point about EI/CPP benefits aren't that the programs are or are not valuable. The importance from a behavioural point of view (as pointed out by Larry Summers) is how the individual believes the benefits they receive from the payments they make. For instance, I believe that gas taxes used to pay for road construction is valuable, but if I (alone) pay an extra $1000 in gas taxes, I don't see any personal benefit (it's not as if the Transport Department uses the money to pave my driveway).

That should be: "individual believes the benefits they receive ARE RELATED TO the payments they make."

Nick, CPP is 4.95 for employee and 4.95 for employer for a total of 9.9. Self-employed pay the full 9.9, but can deduct half of it i.e. take it as a deduction not a credit.

Mike, refundable tax credits, e.g. child tax benefits, GST credit, make a big difference to the progressivity of the income tax system and also significantly influence marginal tax rates.

The problem is that you've lumped EI and CPP into the meaninglessly broad category of "taxes" - i.e. any deduction administered by the government, according to the definition you seem to be using.

The CPP is not a tax, it's an investment; you get back returns based on how much you invest. That is not the case with income tax.

EI is also not a tax, it's an insurance premium. You pay an amount to insure something; in this case the insurance stops paying on earnings over $47,200. So yes, people earning more than that pay a smaller percentage of their income than people below that, but they also don't accrue any insurance benefit above that amount.

If you want to include such things in your calculation to bolster your premise, why not also include car insurance and property insurance into the calculation? Surely some might consider these necessities of life: indeed, car insurance is government-mandated. The fact that something is simply collected by the government does not make it a tax.

I also object to your insinuation that the LICO is the definition of poverty and that there should be no tax on earnings below that. I can't think of anything other than the most poorly-research newspaper articles that refer to the LICO as the "poverty line". Why would being in the loosely-defined category of "low income" exempt one from making any financial contribution, however small and relatively less than others, whatsoever to society?

Mike, if you're interested in this area, check out Kevin Milligan's web page and in particular his Canadian Tax and Credit Simulator. A gift to economist-kind - I can't say enough nice things about Kevin's work. He also has a forthcoming paper in Canadian Public Policy about the progressivity of the Canadian tax/transfer system.

You might also want take a look at some of the research in this area, e.g. the papers by Jon Kesselman (2004) and by Vermaeten, Gillespie and Vermaeten (mid 1980s) in the Canadian Tax Journal. References:

http://www.sfu.ca/mpp-old/04research/pdfs/CPPR_tax_inequality.pdf

http://qed.econ.queensu.ca/pub/cpp/Sept1995/Vermaeten.pdf

"If you want to include such things in your calculation to bolster your premise, why not also include car insurance and property insurance into the calculation?"

Because the premiums you pay are related to the benefits your expected benefits, which is clearly not the case here, for several reasons:

- People who are ineligible to collect EI are still required to pay it
- People who have no realistic chance of losing their job are still required to pay it
- Revenues go into general revenues and are not necessarily related to payments (see Kesselman 1998).

"The fact that something is simply collected by the government does not make it a tax."

Agreed. And the fact that something is called an insurance does not make it the equivalent of car insurance.

Frances: Thanks for the links! I'll have to check out Prof. Milligan's piece. I'm a big fan of Prof. Kesselman's work, as shown above.

"Mike, refundable tax credits, e.g. child tax benefits, GST credit, make a big difference to the progressivity of the income tax system and also significantly influence marginal tax rates."

I should have included the GST credit - mea culpa. There was an implicit assumption in all this that I was looking at a single childless income earner. I should have made that explicit. Will add that to the list of assumptions.

"People who have no realistic chance of losing their job are still required to pay it".

Give me an example. I've seen laid off teachers, public servants, even church ministers.

What you're describing is classic insurance thinking. It's the customer's thinking in the problem of Selection Against the Insurer. The rational economic response is to include as many people in the base as possible. This is no different from things like group health and disability insurance.

"People who are ineligible to collect EI are still required to pay."

This is the only criticism that is fair. However Service Canada would respond that they can't say that you'll move into insured employment in a years time and be collecting in three years. So there are two sides to that argument.

"Revenues go into general revenues and are not necessarily related to payments."

If EI was a private disability plan (DI is the closest relative of EI) you wouldn't make this argument. When a private insurer makes a profit it's OK, when a government does so it's a nasty tax. This also ignores the fact that the Government of Canada is obligated to make up losses in the EI Fund and has done so repeatedly in the last 50 years. The reforms of the early 1990's threw the plan in to consistent surplus.

EI is a hybrid creature between welfare and pure insurance, but that doesn't mean it's a tax for most people.

Insurance depends on cross-subsidization of losses between premium payers. It's an age old struggle between having many members with low claims and therefore a large number of members who think the value of their coverage is marginal and low, and having a small number of members with a high probability of claims and premiums that nobody can afford. It's gone on forever.

Just because you think the risk is low and want out doesn't mean you can get out and the risk isn't there.

"There was an implicit assumption in all this that I was looking at a single childless income earner."

Over 18 and under 65. Not self-employed.

For this group you also need to bear in mind the new working income tax benefit (don't remember it's name) that's available for singles.

Determinant - all I can suggest is that you examine the literature. In either case, it's a tax - the key is, again, as Summers points out, is to determine the level of benefit linkage. We may disagree on the degree, but the benefit linkage is clearly not 100%, as the premiums are not based on any actuarial calculation of the risk at all.

And please refrain from the 'big bad government' stuff. It's hurting my head to be too be criticized from both the right (on my implication that perhaps people under LICO shouldn't be paying income taxes) and on the left (you said government is bad!). It'd be much easier if y'all push from the same side. :)

"Over 18 and under 65. Not self-employed."

I did mention that there were exceptions (see discussion RE: 40% ownership stake. Maybe useful to list the major ones?

"For this group you also need to bear in mind the new working income tax benefit (don't remember it's name) that's available for singles."

I didn't realize how many of these I missed. Again, I'd like to thank everyone for their helpful suggestions. I'm looking forward to polishing this up this week.

I disagree with the literature on a fundamental level. I have a well-grounded view on what constitutes insurance and what constitutes a tax. This difference here is political at root. I look at objective facts and have my opinion. I don't see the fact that some revenue may flow to the government as a tax.

The key question for me is "If this plan were operated by the private sector, would the same structure apply?" Since EI resembles pension plans where employers bear sponsorship risk, and the fact that the Government has LOST money on EI, that is it has had to make up deficits in the EI Fund from the Consolidated Revenue Fund (i.e. income taxes) in the past, there is a good argument to be made that EI premiums aren't a tax.

Consider the case of community-rated health insurance. The benefits linkage isn't 100% either. In fact you're stumbling over the fact that benefits for EI are community-rated based on historic unemployment rates. This is a valid insurance stance, it's just that community rating isn't common anymore since it has mostly passed out of use in Canada.

EI is an insurance plan, not a savings account. There is always a significant risk you won't claim anything.

As for the left and the right, I critique inconsistencies wherever they may be. ;)

Mike -

I won't bother re-iterating the good points Determinant makes, except to also add that benefit linkage doesn't correlate 100% in the case of car insurance either. Here, again, the insurance is government-mandated but the benefit accrues disproportionately to people who have accidents. I have never had a car accident and might prefer to just be a safe driver than to buy insurance, but I recognize that I may some day benefit from it. So too, I do not have a job that allows me to draw EI should I become unemployed, but I recognize that I may get one some day and my past contributions will allow me to draw the benefit.

The EI system could be re-jigged to exempt premiums for people who are not in a situation to immediately enjoy a benefit, at the expense of charging a higher premium to people who do. Would that make the system more "progressive" and address your concerns? Indeed, most of the people you are concerned about in the $37-47K range are actually EI's principle clientele as salaried employees (it's no mistake that they stop insuring benefits above that amount), and a great many high-income self-employed (lawyers, doctors, government employees, university professors, etc) cannot benefit and are actually those ones you identify as unlikely to need it. Doesn't that mean that the higher-income are actually subsidizing the lower-income employed, making the whole system more progressive than your model portrays?

I agree that EI is a tax more than insurance. Premiums are completely insensitive to risk. I don't care where the revenues go--any reasonable insurance would vary premiums according to risk.

I'm with Mike on EI and CPP. Benefit-tax linkages are tricky in practice. Exchanges between individuals and government range the spectrum from buying a bottle at the LCBO that confers a direct benefit to the individual to tax assessments on income to which no direct benefit is attached.

The right way to think about this is to ask--if the EI or CPP premium is raised, does that change my CPP or EI entitlement? The answer in both cases is no. CPP benefits depend on your lifetime pattern of earnings, not how much tax you paid. It so happens that CPP taxes also depend on earnings, but that is beside the point. Same with EI--your benefits depend on your earnings, not how much EI premiums you have paid.

It is true that on a macro scale, budgets do need to balance. (Note that this is enforced much more for the CPP than EI. Anyone who looks at total EI revenue vs EI benefits paid over the last 30 years would be very hard pressed to argue for any tax-benefit linkage.)

However, on the individual scale that matters for Mike's analysis, one's own benefits depend not at all on one's own marginal contribution. They are taxes.

"EI is a hybrid creature between welfare and pure insurance, but that doesn't mean it's a tax for most people."

You have to be careful about the other side - the benefit. I've tried reading all the comments, and I don't think it's been pointed out that for a high-income earner, EI payments won't help all that much. If your EI benefits won't even cover your base expendituures, like mortgage, car insurance, gas, and groceries, then it likely affects your view of the value of the premiums.

However, on a different note...

I would like to see the last charts (the ones including the provincial details) with a column added that shows the population in each of those brackets. I think we would suddenly see why government tax policy is actually **really** hard. You can play with the rates on the upper end all you want - running them either up or down, but to get enough money to run the government, you have to tax people in the middle. This isn't ideology - it's just demographics.

WRT federal taxes, it seems that the regressivity caused by payroll taxes is just an artefact of the maximum insurable or pensionable earnings level for the EI/CPP programs.

Two ways to solve that: raise the insurable or pensionable income limits, or levy the premiums and contributions on higher earners while still capping benefits. Either way, there's problems, e.g. potential six-digit EI bums, or unapologetic redistributionism. Political hell either way.

Determinant btw did well to point out the OAS/GIS factor which is fair comment if CPP was going to be treated as tax rather than as savings.

Andrew: as for making EI premiums vary with risk, wouldn't that compound the problem? i.e. some regions and sectors would have astronomical premiums, employment levels in those regions and sectors would drop, and the risk being insured against would made more likely to happen. Besides, the politics would blow apart the country--nothing like another unity crisis to remind us we're at home!

Chris: do you tax where the people are, or where the money is? If Canada had a fairly equal income distribution, that would be the same thing. But of course there is a demographic effect on CPP balances.

I don't know if the state-run universal pensions are going to fare much worse over the long run than all the other saved claims to future production, represented by other retirement assets. Society as a whole is to a certain degree always a "pay as you go" phenomenon.

With EI, premiums are capped at $747.36. The rich individual making six figures may collect EI, but as his premiums and benefits are capped at the Maximum Insurable Amount. I fail to see how this translates to a "tax". It is implicit that these individuals should have enough savings and assets to see them through, but that doesn't keep them from claiming EI by itself.

It is also apparent that many are missing the fact on how EI is rated. Please see http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Community_rating. Not all insurance in individually risk-rated. It doesn't have to be. That doesn't mean its not insurance.

EI is Community Rated across Canada; the premiums are supposed to balance expenses "over the economic cycle". Benefits vary by region; regions with higher unemployment have longer benefits. This may seem counterintuitive until you reason that if the purpose of EI is to get people off EI, regions with lower unemployment rates should have lower unemployment periods. This is the same sort of reasoning that employers use with Disability Insurance. Most employer group policies will have 1-2 years of "Regular Occupation" Disability and the balance of the period will be the more stringent "Any Occupation" definition. In both cases access to benefits is restricted motivate people to get off of claim.

Hey. Long-time reader first-time commenter. I wanted to get a better picture of individual tax burden and incentives, so I took the values here and wrote a little program to compute retained income (in Ontario) for a given level of income. Of course to do that I had to put in the flat-lining CPP and EI limit. If I missed something I'm open to correction. This excludes the effects on wage from employer contributions.

I graphed the results at http://i.imgur.com/GHSeE.png

You can see there are six pivots there, where going up in income lowers your after-deduction income itself. Those (rounding up to the nearest thousand) are at 11k, 38k, 41k, 75k, 82k, and 128k.

Mike,

Great stuff, fascinating reading -- but unless I'm missing something, your provincial tax rates are too low.
Ontario's top marginal tax rate isn't 40.16 per cent. It's 46.41 per cent.
I think you left out the surtaxes (which are not insignificant) on higher income earners.
See: http://www.rev.gov.on.ca/en/tax/pit/rates.html
Other provinces have similar ratese, whether structured as surtaxes or as additional (and higher) tax brackets.

The comments to this entry are closed.

Search this site

  • Google

    WWW
    worthwhile.typepad.com
Blog powered by Typepad